File Content -
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and
Policy Challenges01
This year’s Economic Survey comes at a time of unusual volatility in the
international economic environment. Markets have begun to swing on fears
that the global recovery may be faltering, while risks of extreme events are
rising. Amidst this gloomy landscape, India stands out as a haven of stability
and an outpost of opportunity. Its macro-economy is stable, founded on the
government’s commitment to fiscal consolidation and low inflation. Its economic
growth is amongst the highest in the world, helped by a reorientation of
government spending toward needed public infrastructure. These achievements
are remarkable not least because they have been accomplished in the face of
global headwinds and a second successive season of poor rainfall.
The task now is to sustain them in an even more difficult global environment. This
will require careful economic management. As regards monetary and liquidity
policy, the benign outlook for inflation, widening output gaps, the uncertainty
about the growth outlook and the over-indebtedness of the corporate sector
all imply that there is room for easing. Fiscal consolidation continues to be
vital, and will need to maintain credibility and reduce debt, in an uncertain
global environment, while sustaining growth. On the government’s “reform-
to-transform” agenda, a series of measures, each incremental but collectively
meaningful have been enacted. There have also been some disappointments—
especially the Goods and Services Tax—which need to be retrieved going forward.
Accelerated structural reforms at the Centre, the dynamism of competitive
federalism, and good economics being good politics could all combine to
maintain the fundamental promise that is India. For now, but not indefinitely,
the sweet spot created by a strong political mandate but, recalibrated to take
account of a weaker external environment, is still beckoningly there.
IntroductIon
1.1 A year ago, the Economic Survey
spoke about the “sweet spot” for the Indian
economy, arising from a combination of a
strong political mandate and a favourable
external environment. At the same time, it
cautioned against unrealistic expectations of “Big Bang” reforms because of the dispersed
nature of power in India and the absence of that
impelling driver—crisis. It argued therefore
in favour of a “persistent, creative and
encompassing incrementalism” as the guide
for prospective action and the benchmark for
retrospective assessment.
CHAPTER
2
1.2 This year’s Survey comes against the
background of an unusually volatile external
environment with significant risks of weaker
global activity and non-trivial risks of extreme
events. Fortifying the Indian economy against
possible spillovers is consequently one obvious
necessity. Another necessity is a recalibration
of expectations.
1.3 If the world economy lurches into crisis
or slides into further weakness, India’s growth
will be seriously affected, for the correlation
between global and Indian growth has been
growing dramatically (Figure 1). Assessments
of India’s performance over the coming year
will therefore need to be conditional. This
is not an advance apology for likely future
performance but the sobering reality of India
becoming “so entwined” with the world.
1.4 Looking backward, the obvious question
is: how has the economy performed against
the standards set in last year’s Survey? India’s
economic performance can be measured
against two distinct benchmarks: India versus
other countries; and India versus its own
medium-term potential. On the first, the Indian
economy has fared well; on the second, steady
progress is being made and there is still scope
for translating potential into actuality. 1.5 Start with the comparisons with other
countries. At a time when the newest normal
for the world economy is one of turbulence and
volatility, India is a refuge of stability and an
outpost of opportunity. Its macro-economy is
robust, and it is likely to be the fastest growing
major economy in the world in 2016. For an
economy where exports have declined due to
weak global demand and private investment
remains weak, India’s economy is performing
remarkably well.
1.6 In part, this performance reflects the
implementation of a number of meaningful
reforms, each incremental, but collectively
meaningful:
•
Creating the palpable and pervasive
sense that corruption at the centre has
been meaningfully addressed, reflected in
transparent auctions of public assets and
non-interference in regulatory decisions;
• Liberalizing foreign direct investment
(FDI) across-the-board, including by
passing the long-awaited insurance bill.
FDI reforms reflect a decisive change
in philosophy, from viewing FDI as
a tolerable necessity to something to
welcome;
Source: World Economic Outlook (WEO), January, 2016 update.
Economic Survey 2015-16
3
• Vigorously pursuing efforts to ease
the cost of doing business, which has
allowed India to advance in cross-country
competitiveness rankings and become the
crucible for “million mutinies” reflected in
the unprecedented dynamism of the start-
up and e-commerce sectors, and in the
interest of large employment-generating
companies (Box 1.4 in the Outlook
section);
• Restoring stability and predictability in
tax decisions, reflected in the settlement
of the Minimum Alternate Tax (MAT)
imposed on foreign companies, and
increasing substantially the limits beyond
which the tax department will file appeals;
• Implementing a major public investment
program to strengthen the country’s
infrastructure and make up for the
deficiency of private investment;
• Instituting a major crop insurance program
to cushion farmers against adversity;
• Limiting farm interventions which had
a first-order effect in moderating overall
inflation;
• Elevating to mission mode the financial
inclusion agenda via the Jan Dhan Yojana
by creating bank accounts for over 200
million people within months. Financial
inclusion will also be furthered by the
licensing of 11 payments banks and 10
small banks;
• Advancing the game-changing JAM
(Jan Dhan Aadhaar Mobile) agenda.
LPG witnessed the world’s largest direct
benefit transfer program, with about 151
million beneficiaries receiving a total of
R29,000 crore in their bank accounts.
The infrastructure is being created for
extending the JAM agenda to other
government programs and subsidies;
• Attempting to change social norms in a
number of areas: open defecation, and
voluntarism in giving up subsidies.
• Undertaking comprehensive reforms of the power sector (especially the UDAY
Scheme); and
• Avoiding policy reversals.
1.7 Yet, there was the perception that
quantity cannot exculpate quality, that
launching and better implementing schemes
were privileged over policy changes, and that
policies to unlock India’s full supply potential
could have been more vigorously advanced.
This perception owes in part to a failure to
aggregate all the individual reforms and hence
to appreciate the sum as more than the parts. It
also owes, though, to some disappointments.
1.8 Approval for the game-changing
GST bills has proved elusive so far; the
disinvestment program fell short of targets,
including that of achieving strategic sales;
and the next stage of subsidy rationalization
is a work-in-progress. Critically, corporate and
bank balance sheets remain stressed, affecting
the prospects for reviving private investment,
a key engine of long term growth.
1.9 Perhaps the underlying anxiety is that
the Indian economy is not realizing its full
potential. It is incontrovertible that India is
still oozing potential. The country’s long run
potential growth rate is still around 8-10 per
cent (Box 1.1 elaborates on this in greater
detail). Realizing this potential requires a push
on at least three fronts.
1.10 First, India has moved away from being
reflexively anti-markets and uncritically
pro-state to being pro-entrepreneurship and
skeptical about the state. But being pro-
industry must evolve into being genuinely pro-
competition, and the legacy of the pervasive
exemptions Raj and corporate subsidies
highlights why favoring business (and not
markets) can actually impede competition.
Similarly, skepticism about the state must
translate into making it leaner, without
delegitimizing its essential roles and indeed
by strengthening it in important areas.
1.11 Key to creating a more competitive
environment will be to address the exit (the
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
4
Chakravyuha) problem which bedevils the
Indian economy and endures as an impediment
to investment, efficiency, job creation and
growth (see Chapter 2). The Indian economy
had moved from socialism with restricted entry
to “marketism” without exit. The government
is undertaking a number of initiatives
such as introducing a new bankruptcy law,
rehabilitating stalled projects, and considering
guidelines for public private partnerships that
can help facilitate exit, thereby improving the
efficiency of the economy.
1.12 Second, major investments in people—
their health and education—will be necessary
to exploit India’s demographic dividend.
Tomorrow’s worker is today’s child or
foetus—born to and raised by today’s mothers.
It would consequently seem important to focus
on “mother and child,” involving maternal
health and early life interventions, which is
the subject of Chapter 5. Raising the necessary
resources for investments in human capital is
discussed in Chapter 7.
1.13 More broadly, the delivery of essential
services is a gargantuan challenge. With
increased devolution of resources, states will
need to expand their capacity and improve
the efficiency of service delivery. That will
require them to shift their focus from outlays
to outcomes, and to learn by monitoring,
innovating, and even erring.
1.14 Improving service delivery in the wake of
the Fourteenth Finance Commission requires
an evolution in the relative roles of the Centre
and the states: the Centre should focus on
improving policies, strengthening regulatory
institutions, and facilitating cooperative
and competitive federalism while the states
mobilize around implementing programs and
schemes to ensure better service delivery.
1.15 Third, while dynamic sectors such
as services and manufacturing tend to grab
public attention, India cannot afford to neglect
its agriculture (Chapter 4). After all, nearly 42 per cent of Indian households derive the bulk
of their income from farming. Smaller farmers
and landless laborers especially are highly
vulnerable to productivity, weather, and market
shocks changes that affect their incomes. The
newly introduced crop insurance schemes
should begin to address these problems to a
great extent.
1.16
Climate change and emerging scarcities
will necessitate a focus on “more for less”,
and hence redressing the current system of
incentives and subsidies, which encourages
using more inputs such as fertilizer, water,
and power, to the detriment of soil quality,
health and the environment. They also
disproportionately benefit rich and large
farmers.
1.17 Despite the many challenges, there
remains considerable room for optimism.
Optimism is engendered by the dynamic of
competitive federalism. States that perform
well are increasingly becoming “models and
magnets.” Successful experiments in one state
are models for others states to emulate by
showing what can be done and stripping away
excuses for inaction and under-performance.
They are also magnets because they attract
resources, talent and technology away from
the lagging states, forcing change via the
channel of “exit.”
1.18 Optimism is reinforced by events of
the last decade that have re-affirmed the
dictum that good economics is good politics,
even as frequent elections complicate the
task of policy-making. Not always and not
everywhere but increasingly, Central and State
governments that have delivered rapid growth
and better governance tend to get re-elected
and vice versa. It is telling, for example, that
the state governments that have been elected
three times have been the ones that have
delivered rapid agricultural growth.
1.19 Furthermore, optimism is also fueled
Economic Survey 2015-16
5
Box 1.1: What is India’s Potential GDP Growth?
India is oozing potential. That is undeniable. But is it measurable?
Typically, economists measure a country’s potential GDP growth in two ways: first, by extrapolating from past
growth; and, second, by projecting the underlying drivers of growth: capital (physical and human), labor, and
productivity. Both have limitations and both rely on a variety of assumptions.
The first methodology has many variants, including the use of Hodrick-Prescott filters. But they are all essentially
mechanical and are really some weighted average of past growth rates. One disadvantage of this method is that
variations in actual growth can induce considerable volatility in estimates of potential growth. But potential
growth should be relatively stable unless there are some fundamental shifts in the underlying policy and
institutional environment.
Estimating potential GDP by projecting the underlying determinants of growth (as done in Rodrik and
Subramanian, “Why India Can Grow at 7 Per Cent a Year or More”, Economic and Political Weekly (EPW)
[2005]) requires assumptions to be made on total factor productivity growth, which can be arbitrary unless they
too are based on past performance which leads to the problems noted abov\
e.
A different way of estimating potential GDP growth is to use a deep determinants-cum-convergence framework.
There is a well-established literature (North, D, “Institutions”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, [1991],
Acemoglu, D and J.A. Robinson, “Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty” , Crown
Business [2012]) that suggests that institutions are a key determinant of long run growth. This is summarized in
Figure 1 below.
by the Indian decision-making process which
allows—hopefully even creates the pressures—
for disappointments to be retrieved. The GST
is within reach; new bankruptcy procedures,
as well as the revival of some big stalled projects
such as Dabhol, illustrate that the exit problem
can be solved; not only is the infrastructure
being created for the game-changing JAM
agenda to be translated into reality, there are numerous silent revolutions taking place all
around the country—sugar and seeds in Uttar
Pradesh, food and kerosene in Andhra Pradesh,
Chandigarh and Puducherry—that are helping
the spread, and hence realizing the promise, of
the JAM agenda (discussed in Chapter 3).
1.20
In sum, for now but not indefinitely, the
sweet spot for India is still beckoningly there.
Contd....
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
6
The upward-sloping line in the figure reflects a strong relationship (on average) between political institutions
and economic development that has been found in empirical research, validating the central argument of the
“institutions matter” hypothesis. However, China and India are outliers (they are far away from the line of best
fit). And the interesting thing is that each of these countries is an exception, or even a challenge, to the relationship
but in opposite ways. India (which is way below the line) is not rich \
enough given its uncontestably vibrant
political institutions. China (which is well above the line) is too rich given its weak democratic institutions.
The assumption is that India and China will mean-revert, that is they will become more typical, and move
towards the line of best fit, over the medium term. Mean reversion can happen in different ways. For China, the
assumption is that this process of becoming a “normal” country will happen via a combination of slower growth
and faster democratization as shown in Figure 2. Indeed, the growth slowdown in China should be seen as a
process of normalization after a period of abnormally high growth. For India, normalization should take the form
of an acceleration of growth shown in the figure below.
India’s potential growth rate can thus be estimated as a reversion to a state of things where its economic
development is consistent with its well-developed political institutions. The question is what is the implied
growth rate that is consistent with this mean reversion.
The basic convergence framework provides a framework for estimating, albeit roughly, India’s potential growth
rate during this process of normalization (see Technical Appendix for the simple algebra of this computation).
According to convergence theory, India’s per capita GDP growth rate (in PPP terms) between 2015 and 2030
should be some multiple of the difference in the initial level of per capita GDP between the US and India in 2015.
That difference is about 2.2 log points. The multiple is called the convergence coefficient—the rate at which
India will catch up with the United States. A reasonable parameter from the literature is that this should be about
2 percent per year, at least for countries that are converging. The East Asians converged at a much faster pace but
others at a slower pace.
The significance of the figure shown above is that since India has under-achieved so far, it must converge at a
faster pace than usual, so that it can revert to the “normal” line. Hence, its convergence coefficient should be
substantially better than 2 percent. These PPP-based growth rates need to be converted into market exchange
rate growth rates. The resulting estimates are shown in the table below for alternative assumptions about this
convergence coefficient.
Contd....
Economic Survey 2015-16
7
Based on this analysis, India’s medium term growth potential is somewhere between 8 and 10 percent. Of course,
this is an estimate of potential, conveying a sense of opportunity. Hard policy choices and a cooperative external
environment will be required to convert opportunity into reality.
Table: China and India’s Potential Growth Rate, 2015-30 (per cent)
Convergence speed (per cent) China
India
2 3.3 6.2
2.5 4.1 7.6
3 5.0 9.0
3.5 5.9 10.4
the Global context
1.21 Since the Economic Survey and
Budget were presented a year ago, the Indian
economy has continued to consolidate the
gains achieved in restoring macroeconomic
stability. Inflation, the fiscal deficit, and the
current account deficit have all declined,
rendering India a relative haven of macro-
stability in these turbulent times. Economic
growth appears to be recovering, albeit at
varying speeds across sectors.
1.22 At the same time, the upcoming
Budget and 2016-17 (FY2017) economic
policy more broadly, will have to contend
with an unusually challenging and weak
external environment. Although the major
international institutions are yet again
predicting that global growth will increase
from its current subdued level, they assess
that risks remain tilted to the downside. This
uncertain and fragile outlook will complicate
the task of economic management for India.
1.23 The risks merit serious attention not
least because major financial crises seem
to be occurring more frequently. The Latin
American debt crisis of 1982, the Asian
Financial crisis of the late 1990s, and the
Eastern European crisis of 2008 suggested
that crises might be occurring once a decade.
But then the rapid succession of crises,
starting with Global Financial Crisis of 2008 and proceeding to the prolonged European
crisis, the mini-crises of 2013, and the China-
provoked turbulence in 2015 all hinted that
the intervals between events are becoming
shorter.
1.24 This hypothesis could be validated
in the immediate future, since identifiable
vulnerabilities exist in at least three
large emerging economies—China, Brazil,
Saudi Arabia—at a time when underlying
growth and productivity developments in
the advanced economies are soft (see Box
1.2). More flexible exchange rates, however,
could moderate full-blown eruptions into less
disruptive but more prolonged volatility.
1.25 One tail risk scenario that India must
plan for is a major currency re-adjustment
in Asia in the wake of a similar adjustment
in China, as such an event would spread
deflation around the world. Another tail risk
scenario could unfold as a consequence of
policy actions—say, capital controls taken to
respond to curb outflows from large emerging
market countries, which would further
moderate the growth impulses emanating
from them.
1.26 In either case, foreign demand is likely
to be weak, forcing India—in the short run—
to find and activate domestic sources of
demand to prevent the growth momentum
from weakening. At the very least, a tail risk
Source: Ministry of Finance calculations
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
8
event would require Indian monetary and
fiscal policy not to add to the deflationary
impulses from abroad. The consolation would be that weaker oil and commodity
prices would help keep inflation and the twin
deficits in check.
Box 1.2: Analytical Taxonomy of Financial Crises, Past and Future
Since the 1980s, external financial crises have followed one of three basic forms: the Latin American, the Asian
Financial Crisis (AFC), or the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) model. So one could ask: in the unlikely event that
a major event did take place in a systematically important emerging market, which form would it follow? The
answer is probably none of the above. The implications would be unlike anything seen in the last 80 years. (The
attached table contains a summary).
In the Latin American debt crisis, governments went on a spending binge financed by foreign borrowing (of
recycled petrodollars) while pegging their exchange rates. The spending led to a classic sequence: economic
overheating, large current account deficits that eventually proved difficult to finance, and finally defaults on the
foreign borrowing. The Indian external crisis of 1991 belonged to this category, although the country did not and
has never defaulted.
In the AFC of the late 1990s, the transmission mechanism was similar—namely, overheating and unsustainable
external positions under fixed exchange rates—but the instigating impulse was private borrowing rather than
government borrowing. The troubles in Eastern Europe in 2008 belonged to this category. The 2013 mini-crises
in a number of emerging markets following the Federal Reserve’s “taper tantrum” were also similar to the Asian
crisis, with the difference that affected countries had more flexible exchange rates which obviated the large
disruptive changes that occur when fixed regimes collapse.
The GFC of 2008, with America as its epicentre, was unique in that it involved a systemically important country
and originated in doubts about its financial system. The effects radiated out globally, with the irony that even
though the problems originated in the American financial system, there was a flight of capital toward
the United
States, which triggered a sharp appreciation of the dollar and significant currency depreciations in emerging
markets. In this way, the GFC, while inflicting an adverse financial shock on the rest of the world, simultaneously
set in motion an adjustment mechanism that helped emerging markets recover from the crisis.
The Japanese crisis was similar to the GFC in terms of the transmission mechanism (asset price bubbles
encompassing equity markets and real estate). But it was dissimilar in that it was corporate rather than household
borrowing that was the instigating impulse. Also, the crisis did not have a systemic financial impact, since Japan
was not a major international banking centre. Nor did it have a major impact on global exports, even though
Japan was (and is) a major global trader, because, as in the GFC, the epicentre’s currency appreciated as the crisis
played itself out.
China’s current situation is similar to the AFC case in that fears about excessive corporate debts—in the context
of slowing growth and changing economic management—are fostering large capital outflows. But the outcome is
less certain, since whereas Asian countries had limited foreign exchange reserves China has more than $3 trillion
in official assets, consequent upon years of running large current account surpluses. This situation gives China
much more space and time to deal with incipient problems, and minimize their consequences, for example, by
allowing a gradual rather than disruptive decline in the exchange rate.
Were a major event in China or another large emerging market to take place nonetheless, it would be very
different from the three categories described above. It would likely involve a large currency depreciation in a
systemically important country which would spread outward as a deflationary/competitiveness shock to the rest
of the world, especially countries competing with it. Consequently, the built-in adjustment mechanism that took
place in the GFC—where the crisis country’s currency appreciated would be absent.
In this sense, a potential tail event in a systemically important emerging market would resemble more the events
of the early 1930s when the UK and then the US went off the gold standard, triggering a series of devaluations
by other countries, leading to a collapse of global economic activity.
Economic Survey 2015-16
9
Table: Anatomical Taxonomy of External Financial Crises
Crisis TypeOriginating
Countries Origin of
problem Manifestation
TriggerExchange
Rate
Regime Remarks
Latin
American Emerging markets
(Latin America 1982; India 1991); Small advanced country
(Greece 2010 onwards) Government
borrowing Current
account deficit Speculative
attack and exchange rate
collapse Fixed rate Greece was
part of euro,
so trigger was sharp rise in
interest rates.
Asian
Financial Crisis Emerging markets
(East Asia 1997-9;
Eastern Europe 2008; Fragile Five 2013); Small advanced
country (Spain 2010) Corporate
borrowing Asset price
bubbles; High corporate leverage “Sudden
stop” of capital
flows and exchange rate
collapse Fixed rate
Fragile Five
had flexible exchange
rates. Spain was part of euro.
Japan Systemically
Important Corporate
borrowing Asset price
bubbles; High corporate leverage Asset price
collapse Floating
exchange rate Ye n
appreciated
after crisis.
Global
Financial Crisis Systemically
Important (US 2008) Bank and
consumer
borrowing Asset price
bubble in housing Correction
in asset prices Flexible
exchange rate US dollar
appreciated.
The NEXT Systemically
Important Corporate
borrowing Rising debt,
asset price bubbles “Sudden
stop” with potential
for sharp
exchange
rate decline Managed
float Crisis
country’s currency could
depreciate
substantially.
the IndIan context
1.27 The Indian economy has continued to
consolidate the gains achieved in restoring
macroeconomic stability. A sense of this
turnaround is illustrated by a cross-country
comparison. In last year’s Survey, we had
constructed an overall index of macro-
economic vulnerability, which adds a
country’s fiscal deficit, current account deficit,
and inflation. This index showed that in 2012
India was the most vulnerable of the major
emerging market countries. Subsequently,
India has made the most dramatic strides in
reducing its macro-vulnerability. Since 2013,
its index has improved by 5.3 percentage
points compared with 0.7 percentage point for
China, 0.4 percentage point for all countries in India’s investment grade (BBB), and a
deterioration of 1.9 percentage points in the
case of Brazil (Figure 2).
1.28
If macro-economic stability is one key
element of assessing a country’s attractiveness
to investors, its growth rate is another. In last
year’s Survey we had constructed a simple
Rational Investor Ratings Index (RIRI) which
combined two elements, growth serving as a
gauge for rewards and the macro-economic
vulnerability index proxying for risks. The
RIRI is depicted in Figure 3; higher levels
indicate better performance. As can be seen,
India performs well not only in terms of the
change of the index but also in terms of the
level, which compares favourably to its peers
in the BBB investment grade and even its
“betters” in the A grade
1. As an investment
1 India is in the BBB investment category according to Fitch rating agency; A is the category just above it.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
10
proposition, India stands out internationally.
Review of Major Developments
1.29 In the Advance Estimates of GDP that
the Central Statistics Office (CSO) released
recently, the growth rate of GDP at constant
market prices is projected to increase to 7.6
per cent in 2015-16 from 7.2 per cent in 2014-
15, mainly because private final consumption
expenditure has accelerated. Similarly, the
growth rate of GVA for 2015-16 is estimated
at 7.3 per cent vis-à-vis 7.1 per cent in 2014-15 (Figures 4(a) and (b)). Although agriculture
is likely to register low growth for the second
year in a row on account of weak monsoons,
it has performed better than last year. Industry
has shown significant improvement primarily
on account of the surprising acceleration in
manufacturing (9.5 per cent vis-à-vis 5.5
per cent in 2014-15). Meanwhile, services
continue to expand rapidly.
1.30 Even as real growth has been
accelerating, nominal growth has been
Source: IMF WEO, October 2015 and January 2016 update.
* BBB is the classification of countries as per Fitch ratings agency in which India falls.
Source: IMF WEO, October 2015 and January 2016 update.
Economic Survey 2015-16
11
Source: CSO
*GVA growth of Q4 is the implied GVA number from Advanced estimates of 2015-16 and Quarterly estimates by CSO
falling, to historically low levels, an unusual
trend highlighted in the Mid-Year Economic
Analysis (MYEA), 2015-16. According to
the Advance Estimates, nominal GDP (GVA)
is likely to increase by just 8.6 (6.8) percent
in 2015-16. In nominal terms, construction is
expected to stagnate, while even the dynamic
sectors (see Box 1.4 for one such example)
of trade and finance are projected to grow by
only 7 to 7
3/4 percent.
1.31 Inflation remains under control (Figure
5). The CPI-New Series inflation has fluctuated around 5
1/2 percent, while measures
of underlying trends—core inflation, rural
wage growth and minimum support price
increases—have similarly remained muted.
Meanwhile, the WPI has been in negative
territory since November 2014, the result
of the large falls in international commodity
prices, especially oil. As low inflation has
taken hold and confidence in price stability
has improved, gold imports have largely
stabilized, notwithstanding the end of a
period of import controls (dotted red lines in
Figure 6).
*Vertical lines in figure 5 indicate the period over which quantitative restrictions on gold imports was in effect (August
2013 to November 2014). Source: CSO. Source: Ministry of Finance.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
12
1.32 Similarly, the external position appears
robust. The current account deficit has
declined and is at comfortable levels; foreign
exchange reserves have risen to US$351.5
billion in early February 2016, and are well
above standard norms for reserve adequacy;
net FDI inflows have grown from US$21.9
billion in April-December 2014-15 to
US$27.7 billion in the same period of 2015-
16; and the nominal value of the rupee,
measured against a basket of currencies,
has been steady (Figures 7(a) to (d)). India
was consequently well-positioned to absorb
the volatility from the U.S. Federal Reserve actions to normalize monetary policy that
occurred in December 2015. Although the
rupee has declined against the dollar, it has
strengthened against the currencies of its
other trading partners.
1.33
The fiscal sector registered three striking
successes: ongoing fiscal consolidation,
improved indirect tax collection efficiency;
and an improvement in the quality of
spending at all levels of government.
1.34 Despite the decline in nominal GDP
growth relative to the Budget assumption
(11.5 per cent in Budget 2015-16 vis-à-vis
8.6 per cent in the Advance Estimates), the
Source: RBI.
Economic Survey 2015-16
13
central government will meet its fiscal deficit
target of 3.9 per cent of GDP, continuing the
commitment to fiscal consolidation. Even
on the IMF’s definition, the fiscal deficit
is expected to decline from 4.2 per cent of
GDP in 2014-15 to 4.0 per cent of GDP in
2015-16. Moreover, the consolidated revenue
deficit has also declined in the first 8 months
(for which data are available) by about 0.8
percentage points of GDP.
1.35 Government tax revenues are expected
to be higher than budgeted levels. Direct
taxes grew by 10.7 per cent in the first 9
months (9M) of 2015-16. Indirect taxes were
also buoyant. In part, this reflected excise
taxes on diesel and petrol and an increase in
the Swachh Bharat cess. The central excise
duty collection from petroleum products
during April to December 2015-16 recorded
a growth of 90.5 per cent and stood at Rs.
1.3 lakh crore as against Rs. 0.7 lakh crore in
the same period last year. Tax performance
also reflected an improvement in tax
administration because revenues increased
even after stripping out the additional revenue
measures (ARMs). Indirect tax revenues
grew by 10.7 per cent (without ARMs) and
34.2 per cent (with ARMs). Table 1 shows
that tax buoyancy of direct and indirect taxes
improved in 2015-16 vis-à-vis the average
of the last three years, although more so for
indirect taxes.
Table 1: Tax buoyancy
Base Growth
Revenue Growth Implied Buoyancy
Year DT
IDT DTIDT
2012-13 15.118.525.8 1.21.7
2013-14 11.413.5 4.11.20.4
2014-15 12.78.28.00.60.6
Avg. 2012-15 13.113.412.6 1.01.0
9M 2015 8.39.211.7 1.11.4
Note: 1. Base is summation of GVA in manufacturing and services at current market price.
2. Annual numbers are average of four quarters in that year
DT= Direct Tax IDT= Excise tax plus service tax 9M= \
April-December
1.36 The fiscal stance matters not just
for macro-economic outcomes but also
for the quality of spending. The budget
envisaged an improvement in quality by
shifting expenditures away from current to
capital expenditures. With the acceptance
of the Fourteenth Finance Commission
recommendations, and the large devolution
toward the states as well as re-structuring of
the centrally sponsored schemes, the quality
of expenditure must increasingly be assessed
from a general government (i.e. combining
the center and the states) perspective. This is
done in greater detail in Box 1.3.
1.37 The main findings are that a welcome
shift in the quality of spending has occurred
from revenue to investment, and towards
social sectors. Aggregate public investment
has increased by about 0.6 per cent of GDP
in the first 8 months of this fiscal year, with
contributions from both the Centre (54 per
cent) and states (46 per cent).
outlook
Real GDP growth
1.38 Real GDP growth for 2015-16 is
expected to be in the 7 to 7
3/4 range, reflecting
various and largely offsetting developments
on the demand and supply sides of the Indian
economy. Before analyzing these factors,
however, it is important to step back and note
one important point.
Source: CSO and Controller General of Accounts.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
14
Box 1.3: Assessing the Quality of General Government Spending in FY2016
The 2015-16 Union budget envisaged an improvement in the quality of expenditure, shifting resources from
current to capital spending and devoting more resources to the agricultural sector at a time of farm distress.
At the same time, the recommendations of the Fourteenth Finance Commission, which were accepted by
the government, implied that a much greater portion of revenues would be spent by the states. As a result,
understanding whether the shift in Union strategy has been successful requires analysing general government
(Centre plus states) expenditures, and not just those of the Centre.
In continuation of the analysis done for the Mid-Year Economic Analysis (MYEA) 2015-16, which covered
the first half (H1) of 2015-16, we now report the results of this analysis for the first 8 months of this fiscal year
(FY2016). These results are also illustrated in the figures below. Two points are noteworthy.
First, there was a significant increase in aggregate capital expenditure of the general government.
1 Such spending
increased by 0.6 percentage points of GDP2 (Figure 1). Disaggregating further reveals that the increase in capital
expenditures occurred both in the Centre and states, with the former contributing 54 per cent and the latter 46 per cent.
Thus, the overall budgetary strategy of accelerating public investment s\
eems to be working at an all-India level.
Second, in the first 8 months of FY2016, general government expenditure witnessed an uptick in the three major
social sectors—education, health, and agriculture and rural development—both as a share of GDP and in real
terms
3 (Figure 2 & 3). For example, real expenditure on education, health, and agriculture and rural development
recorded growth of 4.7 per cent, 9 per cent and 8.1 per cent, respectively. Available data does not allow for a
further disaggregation of these developments into contributions by the c\
entre and states.
1 Capital expenditure for the Centre includes loans and advances whereas capital expenditure for the states does not due to
non-availability of data.
2 For simplicity, the GDP for the full year has been divided equally across the year.
3 Health expenditure, and Agriculture and Rural Development expenditures have been deflated by the relevant CPI indices.
Economic Survey 2015-16
15
1.39 India’s long-run potential GDP growth
is substantial, about 8-10 percent (Box 1.1).
But its actual growth in the short run will
also depend upon global growth and demand.
After all, India’s exports of manufactured
goods and services now constitute about 18
percent of GDP, up from about 11 percent a
decade ago.
1.40 Reflecting India’s growing globalization,
the correlation between India’s growth rate
and that of the world has risen sharply to
reasonably high levels. For the period 1991-
2002 this correlation was 0.2. Since then, the
correlation has doubled to 0.42 (Figure 1). In
other words, a 1 percentage point decrease in
the world growth rate is now associated with
a 0.42 percentage point decrease in Indian
growth rates.
1.41 Accordingly, if the world economy
remains weak, India’s growth will face
considerable headwinds. For example, if the
world continues to grow at close to 3 percent
over the next few years rather than returning
to the buoyant 4-4½ per cent recorded during
2003-2011, India’s medium-term growth
trajectory could well remain closer to 7-7½
per cent, notwithstanding the government’s
reform initiatives, rather than rise to the
8-10 per cent that its long-run potential suggests. In other words, in the current global
environment, there needs to be a recalibration
of growth expectations and consequently of
the standards of assessment.
1.42 Turning to the outlook for 2016-17, we
need to examine each of the components of
aggregate demand: exports, consumption,
private investment and government.
1.43 To measure the demand for India’s
exports, we calculate a proxy-weighted
average GDP growth rate of India’s export
partners. The weights are the shares of
partner countries in India’s exports of
goods and services. We find that this
proxy for export demand growth declined
from 3.0 percent in 2014 to 2.7 per cent in
2015, which helps explain the deceleration
in India’s non-oil exports, although the
severity of the slowdown—in fact, a decline
in export volume—went beyond adverse
external developments (Figure 8). Current
projections by the IMF indicate that trading
partner growth this demand will improve
marginally this year to about 2.8 percent.
But the considerable downside risks suggest
that it would be prudent not to count on a big
contribution to GDP growth from improving
export performance.
1.44 On the domestic side, two factors could
boost consumption. If and to the extent
Source: RBI.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
16
that the Seventh Pay Commission (7th PC)
is implemented, increased spending from
higher wages and allowances of government
workers will start flowing through the
economy. If, in addition, the monsoon returns
to normal, agricultural incomes will improve
(see Box 1.5), with attendant gains for rural
consumption, which over the past two years
of weak rains has remained depressed.
1.45 Against this, the disappearance of
much of last year’s oil windfall would work
to reduce consumption growth. Current
prospects suggest that oil prices (Indian crude
basket) might average US$ 35 per barrel next
fiscal year compared with US$ 45 per barrel
in 2015-16. The resulting income gain would
amount roughly equivalent to 1 percentage
point of GDP – an 18 per cent price decline
times a share of net oil imports in GDP of 6
percent. But this would be half the size of last
year’s gain, so consumption growth would
slow on this account next year.
1.46 According to analysis done by Credit
Suisse, (non-financial) corporate sector
profitability has remained weak, falling by 1
percent in the year to December 2015.
2 This
decline reflected a sharp deterioration in the
financial health of the metals—primarily
steel—companies, which have now joined
the ranks of companies under severe financial
stress. As a result, the proportion of corporate
debt owed by stressed companies, defined as
those whose earnings are insufficient to cover
their interest obligations, has increased to 41
percent in December 2015, compared to 35
percent in December 2014.
3 In response to
this stress, companies have once again been
compelled to curb their capital expenditures
substantially. 1.47
Finally, the path for fiscal consolidation
will determine the demand for domestic
output from government. The magnitude of
the drag on demand and output will be largely
equal to the size of consolidation, assuming a
multiplier of about 1.
1.48 There are three significant downside
risks. Turmoil in the global economy could
worsen the outlook for exports and tighter
financial conditions significantly. Second, if
contrary to expectations oil prices rise more
than anticipated, this would increase the drag
from consumption, both directly, and owing
to reduced prospects for monetary easing.
Finally, the most serious risk is a combination
of the above two factors. This could arise if
oil markets are dominated by supply-related
factors such as agreements to restrict output
by the major producers.
1.49 The one significant upside possibility
is a good monsoon. This would increase
rural consumption and, to the extent that it
dampens price pressures, open up further
space for monetary easing (Box 1.6).
1.50 Putting these factors together, we
expect real GDP growth to be in the 7 to 7
3/4
per cent range, with downside risks because
of ongoing developments in the world
economy. The wider range in the forecast
this time reflects the range of possibilities
for exogenous developments, from a rebound
in agriculture to a full-fledged international
crisis; it also reflects uncertainty arising from
the divergence between growth in nominal
and real aggregates of economic activity.
2 As measured by EBITDA, a common measure of cash flow profits; it refers to earnings before interest, taxes,
depreciation, and amortization.
3 An interest coverage ratio (ICR) less than 1 implies that the corporation is under financial stress, since its
earnings are not sufficient to service its interest obligations. Research indicates that an interest cover of below
2.5x for larger companies and below 4x for smaller companies is considered below investment grade. ICR is
typically measured by calculating the ratio of earnings before interest \
and taxes (EBIT) to interest obligations.
Economic Survey 2015-16
17
Box 1.4: Startups and Dynamism
Box 1.5: El Niño, La Niña and Forecast for FY 2017 Agriculture
One part of the economy that is witnessing unusual dynamism is the start\
-up sector, focused on e-commerce and
financial services. As of January 2016, there were 19,400 technology-enabled startups in India, of which 5,000
had been started in 2015 alone.
1 No less than 2000 of the startups have been backed by venture capital/angel
investors since 2010, of which 1005 were created in 2015 alone. Indian start-ups raised $3.5 billion in funding
in the first half of 2015, and the number of active investors in India increased from 220 in 2014 to 490 in 2015.
2
As of December 2015, eight Indian startups belonged to the ‘Unicorn’ club (valuations greater than $1 billion).
It is important that start-ups, too, see “exit” (the theme of Chapter 2), which would take the form of these
companies being listed, allowing the original private investors to cash in on the initial investment, and plough it
back into other similar ventures. Exit valuations in India are still low but are expected to increase as the impact
of new SEBI policies on listings comes into effect, and as equity markets in general revive from current low
valuations caused by a sense of gloom in the global economy.
1 Based on the research done by Your Story and iSPIRT.
2 NASSCOM report titled “Startup India-Momentous Rise of the Indian Startup Ecosystem”.
From time to time, agricultural production is affected by El Niño, an abnormal warming of the Pacific waters near
Ecuador and Peru, which disturbs weather patterns around the world. The 2015 El Niño has been the strongest
since 1997, depressing production over the past year. But if it is followed by a strong La Niña, there could be a
much better harvest in 2016-17.
The 1997 episode lasted roughly from April 1997 to June 1998. During these 15 months, the Oceanic Nino Index
(ONI) – which compares east-central Pacific Ocean surface temperatures to their long-term average and is used
by the US National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration (NOAA) for identifying El Niño events – was
consistently positive and greater than 0.5 degrees Celsius.
The current El Niño started around February 2015; most climate models predict a return to “neutral” conditions
not before May 2016. That makes it just as long as the 1997-98 event. Also, in terms of intensity, it is comparable
to that of 1997-98: The most recent Oceanic Nino Index (ONI) value of 2.3 degree Celsius for November
2015-January 2016 tied with the level for the same period of 1997-98.
An extended and strong El Niño explains why India had a deficient south-monsoon and dry weather lasting
through the winter this time. The prolonged moisture stress from it has, in turn, impacted both kharif as well as
the rabi crop. The figure below shows that average agricultural growth in El Niño years since between 1981-82
and 2015-16 has been -2.1 per cent compared with a period average of 3. \
There is a silver lining here, though. Since 1950, there have been 22 El\
Niño events of varying durations and
intensities, according to NOAA data. But out of the 21 prior to this one, 9 have been followed by La Niña,\
involving an abnormal cooling of sea surface waters along the tropical west coast of South America with an ONI
less than minus 0.5 degrees Celsius. This phenomenon – there have been 14 such events since 1950 – has been
associated with normal-to-excess monsoons in India, which may be a by-pr\
oduct of atmospheric convection
activity shifting to the north of Australia.
Now, it is important that some of the strongest El Niño years (1997-98, 1972-73, 2009-10,\
1986-87 and 1987-88,
ranked in the order of strength and of which the last four produced drou\
ghts in India) were followed by La Niña
episodes, resulting in bumper harvests. The possibility of this being repeated in 2016 after the second strongest El
Niño on record cannot be ruled out. The figure below shows, for example, that average growth in La Niña years
was 8.4 per cent, substantially higher than the period average.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
18
But there is a big catch. El Niño, as of now, continues to be “strong” and is only gradually weakening. It will
enter neutral zone only with the onset of summer. NOAA’s latest forecast assigns only a 22 per cent probability
of La Niña developing in June-July-August, going up to 50 per cent for September-October-November. The
Australian Bureau of Meteorology suggests the “neutral” state as the “most likely for the second half of the
year”.
In other words, one shouldn’t expect La Niña conditions to develop before the second half of the \
southwest
monsoon season (June-September). Even if it develops, the translation into actual rainfall in India could take
time. The effects of the 2015 El Niño, after all, were felt only from July, although the east-central Pacific sea
surface temperature anomalies began in February.
In sum, La Niña is unlikely to deliver its full bounty in the coming monsoon, or at least not until late
in the kharif season. That doesn’t, however, mean the monsoon is going to be bad, especially when all
models are pointing to a very low probability of a repeat El Niño happening this year. The monsoon
could also be good due to other favourable factors such as a “positiv\
e Indian Ocean Dipole”. The latter
phenomenon – where the western tropical Indian Ocean waters near Africa become warmer relative to
those around Indonesia – prevented at least two El Niño years (1997 and 2006) from resulting in droughts
in India.
The policy implication of such a cautious prognosis is that the government should be ready with a contingency
plan for a monsoon, especially after two successive drought years. Declaring minimum support prices well
before kharif sowing operations, incentivizing farmers to produce crops most prone to domestic supply pressures
(such as pulses), and timely contracting of imports of sensitive commodities would be essential components of
this strategy.
Economic Survey 2015-16
19
Box 1.6: Addressing the Twin Balance Sheet Challenge
One of the most critical short-term challenges confronting the Indian economy is the twin balance sheet (TBS)
problem—the impaired financial positions of the Public Sector Banks (PSBs) and some large corporate houses—
what we have hitherto characterized as the ‘Balance Sheet Syndrome with Indian characteristics’. By now, it is
clear that the TBS problem is the major impediment to private investment, and thereby to a full-fledged economic
recovery.
The problems in the banking system have been growing for some time. Stressed assets (nonperforming loans
plus restructured assets) have been rising ever since 2010, impinging on capital positions, even as the strictures
of Basel III loom ever closer on the horizon. Banks have responded by limiting the flow of credit to the real
economy so as to conserve capital, while investors have responded by pushing down bank valuations, especially
over the past year. The shares of many banks now trade well below their book value.
This balance sheet vulnerability is in some ways a mirror and derivative of similar frailties in the corporate sector,
especially the large business houses that borrowed heavily during the boom years to invest in infrastructure and
commodity-related businesses, such as steel. Corporate profits are low while debts are rising, forcing firms to cut
investment to preserve cashflow.
This situation is not sustainable; a decisive solution is needed. But finding one is difficult. For a start, given the
intertwining set of problems, solutions must strengthen both sets of balance sheets. Some steps have already been
taken. In August last year, the government launched the Indradhanush scheme, which includes a phased program
for bank recapitalization. Meanwhile, the RBI initiated the 5:25 and SDR schemes, which create incentives for
the banks to come together with their borrowers to rehabilitate stressed assets. These are good initial steps which
might require follow-up.
Resolving the TBS challenge comprehensively would require 4 Rs : Recognition, Recapitalization, Resolution,
and Reform. Banks must value their assets as far as posible close to true value (recognition) as the RBI has been
emphasizing; once they do so, their capital position must be safeguarded via infusions of equity (recapitalization)
as the banks have been demanding; the underlying stressed assets in the corporate sector must be sold or
rehabilitated (resolution) as the government has been desiring; and future incentive\
s for the private sector and
corporates must be set right (reform) to avoid a repetition of the pro\
blem, as everyone has been clamouring.
But there is a needed sequence to these 4 Rs: Recognition must come first, but it must be accompanied by an
adequate supply of resources; otherwise, banks will be vulnerable. Given the tight fiscal position, where might
the resources to recapitalise PSB’s come from?
One possible source is the public sector’s own balance sheet. For example, the government could sell off assets
that it no longer wants to hold, such as certain nonfinancial companies, and use the proceeds to make additional
investments in the PSBs. This option is reasonably well understood. What is less appreciated is that RBI could
do the same. That is to say it could redeploy its capital as well.
Like all financial firms, central banks hold capital to provide a buffer against the risks they take. In the case
of central banks, risks arise because the value of the foreign exchange reserves in terms of domestic currency
fluctuates along with the exchange rate, while the value of the government securities they own changes as interest
Source: Bank for International Settlements (BIS).
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
20
rates move. Measuring these risks and calculating how much buffer should be provided against them is difficult.
For that reason, central bank capital holdings vary widely.
The figure above depicts the ratio of shareholder equity to assets for various central banks. Shareholder equity
is defined to include capital plus reserves (built through undistributed retained earnings) plus revaluation and
contingency accounts. The chart shows that RBI is an outlier with an equity share of about 32 per cent, second
only to Norway and well above that of the U.S. Federal Reserve Bank and the Bank of England, whose ratios
are less than 2 per cent. The conservative European Central Bank (ECB) and some EM central banks have much
higher ratios, but even they do not approach the level of the RBI.
If the RBI were to move even to the median of the sample (16 per cent), this would free up a substantial amount
of capital to be deployed for recapitalizing the PSBs.
Of course, there are wider considerations that need to be taken into account. Most important, any such move would
need to be initiated jointly and cooperatively between the government and the RBI. It will also be critical to ensure
that any redeployment of capital would preserve the RBI’s independence, integrity, and financial soundness—and
be seen to do so. At this stage, what is important is the broader point: that funds for recapitalization can be found,
at least to a certain extent, by reallocating capital that already exist\
s on the public sector’s balance sheet.
Once the resources to back recognition are identified, the remaining 2 Rs (Resolution and Reform) can be pursued
with vigour. There are many options here, including creating “bad banks” to imp\
lement the four Rs.
Inflation
1.51 For most of the current fiscal year,
inflation has remained quiescent, hovering
within the RBI’s target range of 4-6 percent.
But looming on the horizon is the increase
in wages and benefits recommended for
government workers by the Seventh Pay
Commission (7
th PC). If the government
accepts this recommendation, would it
destabilize prices and inflation expectations?
Most likely, it will not. 1.52 The historical evidence is clear on this
point. Figure 9 illustrates the experience of
the Sixth Pay Commission (6
th PC). It plots
the monthly increase in salaries during the
period of the award, from September 2008 –
September 2009, against non-food inflation.
(At that time, overall inflation was rising due
to a sharp increase in global food prices.)
The figure shows that the 6
th PC award barely
registered on inflation despite the lumpiness
of the award, owing to the grant of arrears.
If the 6
th PC award barely registered, the 7th
Source: CSO, 6th Pay Commission report, Budget documents and CGA.
*Reflecting the phased implementation of the 6
th PC, the vertical lines indicate the timing of grant of arrears.
Economic Survey 2015-16
21
Source: RBI.
4 The weight of rented government housing in the overall CPI is 0.35 per cent. But this includes central and state
governments and public sector undertakings. Since only central government housing allowances are relevant,
the impact on the CPI would be further moderated.
PC is unlikely to either, given the relative
magnitudes: even if fully implemented, the
expected wage bill (including railways) will
go up by around 52 per cent under the 7
th PC
vis-à-vis 70 per cent under the 6
th PC.
1.53 This outcome may seem surprising.
Why would such a large wage increase have
so little impact on inflation? There are three
reasons. Most important is a broad theoretical
point. In principle, inflation reflects the
degree to which aggregate demand exceeds
aggregate supply. And pay awards determine
only one small part of aggregate demand. In
fact, they do not even determine government
demand: that depends on the overall fiscal
deficit, which is the difference between how
much the state is injecting into the economy
through overall spending and how much
it is taking away through taxes. Since the
government remains committed to reducing
the fiscal deficit, the pressure on prices will
diminish, notwithstanding the wage increase.
1.54 That said, theory does suggest that
a sharp increase in public sector wages
could affect inflation if it spilled over into
private sector wages and hence private
sector demand. But currently this channel is muted, since there is considerable slack
in the private sector labour market, as
evident in the softness of rural wages (see
Figure 4). And even if private sector wage
increases nonetheless do quicken somewhat,
the existence of substantial capacity under-
utilization (Figure 10) suggests that firms
might find it difficult to pass the cost increase
onto consumer prices.
1.55
Finally, there will be some mechanical
impact of the increase in the house rent
allowance (HRA) on the housing component
of the CPI. But this effect is likely to be modest
between 0.15 and 0.3 percentage points.
4 And
even then it will merely have a one-off effect
on the level of the CPI, rather than the rate
of inflation going forward, which is the real
target of the RBI.
1.56 The outlook for inflation will
consequently depend on other factors. On
the domestic side, another year of below-
potential growth will mean that the output
gap (reflected for example in the declining
capacity utilization) will widen further. As
a result, there will be additional downward
pressure on underlying inflation, which has
already fallen below 5 percent, as measured
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
22
Source: CSO.
5 Of course, bank lending rates have also been influenced by weaknesses in firm balance sheets, which increases
the risks of providing credit to them.
able to meet its target of 5 percent by March
2017. Indeed, with the current stance, there
is a possibility of undershooting. While the
current policy rate seems “neutral” in that it
is only modestly higher than consumer price
inflation, liquidity conditions are unusually
tight, impeding the passthrough of recent
declines in policy rates to the actual bank
rates faced by borrowers (see Box 1.7).
5
1.59 Figure 12 depicts the situation. It
shows a measure of the tightness of monetary
conditions: the gap between bank lending
(base) rates and nominal GVA growth. If the
difference is negative, then nominal GVA
growth—and for the average firm, revenue
growth—is increasing faster than interest
is accruing on its debts. In that sense, the
monetary stance poses little problems for
the corporate sector. But if interest rates are
higher than nominal GDP growth, firms’
cash flows are being squeezed. If firms then
respond by curbing price increases in order
to boost sale volumes sales and cash flow,
this will put downward pressure on inflation.
The chart shows that this is indeed what has
broadly been happening this year.
by services inflation excluding the oil-related
sub-indices (Figure 11). Meanwhile, if the
monsoon returns to normal, food prices
will ease, especially since the government
remains committed to disciplined increases
in MSPs for cereals, and rural wage growth
remains muted.
1.57
Further relief should come from abroad.
Oil prices have plunged in the first two months
of 2016, as have some commodity prices,
suggesting that input prices are likely to be
lower next fiscal year. Beyond this factor lie
other deflationary forces. As growth in China
continues to slow, excess capacity there could
continue to increase, which will put further
downward pressure on the prices of tradable
goods all around the world. Part of this might
be offset by upward pressure coming from
a depreciation of the rupee, especially if
the Federal Reserve Bank continues to raise
interest rates, prompting capital to reflow to
the U.S, although the prospects of aggressive
Fed action are receding. On balance the risk
to imported pressures, as with domestic
pressures, remains firmly to the downside.
1.58 All this suggests that the RBI should be
Economic Survey 2015-16
23
6 The base rate for Q4 is taken to be the base rate for January 2016.
1.60 For all these reasons, we project that
CPI inflation will ease to between 4
1/2 - 5
per cent in 2016-17. We therefore think
that the effective stance of monetary policy
could be relaxed and in two ways. First, by
easing liquidity conditions to make them
consistent with the current policy rate (Box
1.7). Second, by further lowering the policy
rate consistent with meeting the inflation
target while supporting weakening economic
activity and corporate balance sheets. Robust
Source: CSO and RBI.
measured growth of real GDP may not
warrant an easing of monetary conditions.
But a risk framework combined with a focus
on the more reliable nominal aggregates is
useful. If, in fact, real growth is weaker than
suggested by the headline number, easing is
appropriate. On the other hand, if real GDP
growth is indeed robust, the implied dis-
inflation is large, mitigating the inflationary
risks of easing.
Box 1.7 What Explains the Incomplete Passthrough of Monetary Policy?
According to the February 2016 policy statement, the RBI has shifted to an accommodative policy stance.
Without doubt, policy rates have been reduced substantially: in 2015, there were no less than four rate cuts
cumulating to 125 basis points, including a 50 basis point cut at the October meeting. But there has been much
less “accommodation” in bank lending rates, which have only fallen by around 50 basis points. What explains
the failure of passthrough from policy rates to bank rates?
Figure 1 illustrates the transmission problem. It shows that the gaps between policy rates and bank rates have
increased significantly over the past year. For example, deposit rates before the first rate cut were about 50 basis
points higher than the policy rate, whereas now they are around 75 basis points higher. The lending rate spread,
meanwhile, has increased by even more, from 200 basis points to 275 basi\
s points.
Many commentators have emphasized that transmission is limited by high administered and small savings
rates. The argument is that banks worry that if they cut their deposit rates, customers will flee to small savings
instruments. Recognizing this, the government has reduced rates on some small savings schemes to make them
more responsive to market conditions. But it is also clear from the chart that the small saving schemes don’t
always constrain passthrough. For example, the June rate cut was followed by a large reduction in deposit rates
whereas the much larger October cut was barely passed on at all. And the small saving schemes cannot explain
why the reductions that have taken place in deposit rates have not led to commensurate reductions in lending
rates.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
24
Contd....
It consequently seems that additional factors are at work. One possible factor could be changes in liquidity
conditions as these can reinforce or negate the changes in policy rates. The reason is straightforward: if liquidity
conditions are tight, commercial banks will be extra cautious about passing on policy rate cuts into lowe\
r deposit
rates, for fear of losing customers and hence more liquidity.
Figure 2 measures the tightness of monetary conditions in terms of quantities, plotting the RBI’s provision of
funds in the form of overnight and term repos (the “LAF” or Liquidity Adjustment Facility) in response to banks’
demand for liquidity (The LAF is, by definition, a measure of the demand for liquidity). After the June rate cut,
bank borrowing under the LAF fell to zero on average, in line with the RBI’s strategy of easing its monetary
stance. But around the time of the October cut, something changed: suddenly, banks began to borrow again,
demanding an average of R1 lakh crore per day, rising to R1.75 lakh crore per day by February 2016.
Figures 3 and 4 show how the liquidity tightness has shown up in prices,\
that is to say short-term market interest
rates most influenced by RBI policy. In the periods following the first three rate cuts, the spread between the
91 day t-bill rate and the repo rate declined. But it increased sharply starting in August and continuing after the
October rate cut (Figure 3). Similarly, in the period following the first three rate cuts, the call money rate was
below the repo rate, signalling easy liquidity conditions. After the October cut, that wedge has disappeared,
signalling a tightening of liquidity (Figure 4).
Source: RBI.
* Vertical Lines in all these boxes refer to dates when repo rate changes were announced.
Source: RBI.
Economic Survey 2015-16
25
What the quantity and price data suggest is that starting in late 2015 liquidity has been tightening even as policy
rates have been cut. The consequence is that market interest rates and exchange rates are higher than otherwise,
with implications for domestic growth, exports, and the health of the ov\
er-indebted corporate sector.
Source: RBI.Source: RBI.
MedIuM-terM FIscal FraMework
1.61 The 2016-17 fiscal stance needs to be
assessed in two contexts. Most obviously, it
needs to be evaluated against the likely short-
term outlook for growth and inflation. At
the same time, it also needs to be framed in
a medium-term context. That’s because the
most fundamental task of budget policy is to
preserve fiscal sustainability. The government
needs to be in a strong position tomorrow to repay the debts it is incurring today. And it
needs to be seen to possess this strength.
1.62 Governments adopt various targets to
achieve and signal fiscal sustainability. These
include the overall deficit, the primary deficit,
the revenue deficit, and the debt-to-GDP
ratio. In principle, sustainable ratios are very
much time, country, and history-contingent
(Reinhart, Rogoff, and Savastano, 2003).
But pinning down a relationship between
7
Reinhart, C., K. Rogoff, and M. A. Savastano, 2003, “Debt Intolerance”, NBER Working paper No. 9908.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
26
these contingencies and targets is difficult
to do scientifically. Accordingly, countries
often adopt targets established by others. For
example, countries in other regions adopted
targets of 3 percent of GDP for the fiscal
deficit and 60 percent for the debt-to-GDP
ratio as these had been adopted by Eurozone
economies under the Stability and Growth
Pact (SGP).
1.63 The clearest sign that a government is
on a sustainable path is the direction of its
debt-to-GDP ratio. If this ratio is declining,
then the government’s fundamental fiscal
strength is improving. For much of the
period since the 2008-09 the government
has run large annual deficits in order to
reflate the economy. Initially, the impediment
was the large annual deficits that the
government incurred as it sought to reflate
the economy. These deficits were eventually
curtailed, but macro imbalances nonetheless
continued to grow, leading by 2013-14 to the
second impediment: a sharp exchange rate
depreciation that inflated the rupee value of
foreign debts.
1.64 As a result, overall government debt
continued to grow as fast as GDP, keeping
the debt ratio of the consolidated government
(Centre plus states) near 67 per cent of GDP.
This ratio is high compared to some countries
in Emerging Asia, India’s credit rating peers.
Accordingly, the government is determined
to break the post-GFC trend, and finally put
the debt ratio on a downward path toward
more comfortable levels.
1.65 For this reason, there are strong
arguments to stick to a path of aggressive fiscal
consolidation as envisaged at the time of the
last budget. Such a low deficit would not only
curtail the debt accumulation, but would also
offer some wider advantages. To begin with,
it would mean that the government would
be delivering on a commitment, thereby
reinforcing its credibility, which is one of the
most precious assets that any authority can
command. Conversely, it is far from clear why such a commitment would be abandoned
when the economy is growing at more than
7 per cent. Such rapid growth would seem
to provide ample revenues for the Budget,
while enabling the economy to withstand
the reduction in government demand. So,
credibility and optimality seem to argue for
adhering to the 3.5 percent of GDP target.
1.66 However, there are also arguments on
the other side. With respect to feasibility, two
factors complicate the fiscal task in 2016-17
and beyond:
•
The Seventh Pay Commission has
recommended that government wages and
allowances be increased significantly. Full
implementation of this pay award--which
the government will decide on--would add
about ½ percent of GDP to the Centre’s
wage bill.
• Public investment may need to be
increased further to address a pressing
backlog of infrastructure needs. Such an
increase would merely return spending
to its 2010-11 level of around 2 percent
of GDP, well below the level in other
emerging markets.
1.67 Taking these factors into account, the
Centre’s deficit could swell substantially. As
a result, achieving the original could prove
difficult unless there are tax increases or
cuts in expenditures. There is some scope
to increase receipts from disinvestment and
spectrum auctions to realize which will
require effort.
1.68 Second, even the desirability of a strategy
of aggressive fiscal consolidation could
be questioned. This is because the current
environment is fraught with risks, which
threaten all the engines of India’s growth, as
explained earlier. It would consequently seem
important for the government to “purchase
insurance” against these downside risks --
rather than reduce fiscal demand significantly
and take the chance of precipitating their
realization. Data uncertainty reinforces the
Economic Survey 2015-16
27
need for purchasing insurance.
1.69 But if the deficit target were to be
relaxed, two questions would need to be
answered. First, what would happen to interest
rates? The lower the fiscal deficit, the lower
the borrowing requirement, and possibly
the lower the interest rate on government
securities, which would be very helpful to
companies facing debt servicing difficulties.
International empirical research, however,
suggests that the impact of deficits on long-
term rates is typically small and uncertain.
The reason for this is straightforward:
long-term rates are basically determined
by expectations of the future path of short-
term rates. And this expected path typically
depends largely on the long-term outlook for
growth and inflation-and, not necessarily on
the current year’s fiscal deficit.
1.70 In India’s case, the impact of fiscal
deficits on long-term rates might be somewhat
larger than elsewhere. That’s because most
government securities (G-secs) are held by
banks, and banks have limited capacity to
absorb bond supplies. This risk might seem
particularly pertinent because over the past
few years’ banks have accumulated large
holdings of G-secs, exceeding by a large
margin the statutory liquidity ratio (SLR)
minima that they are required to hold.
Moreover, they will be acquiring sizeable
amounts of state bonds over the next few
years as bank loans to electricity distribution
companies are securitized under the UDAY
scheme. So, banks’ appetite for additional
bond issues might seem to be limited.
1.71 In fact, the risk of oversupply seems
fairly small. For a start, a reduction in the
fiscal deficit – even to one somewhat higher
than 3.5 percent of GDP – implies a lower net
bond issue, relative to GDP. And banks might
actually be eager to purchase additional
G-secs, since falling oil prices could lead
to lower inflation, which could then lead to
lower interest rates and capital gains on their holdings. At the same time, foreign portfolio
investors might also increase their purchases,
since the RBI has been relaxing the limits
on their G-sec investments. Conversely, if
foreign inflows prove small, the RBI itself
may need to buy G-secs to assure an adequate
increase in money supply. Finally, if demand
proves weak the government can always scale
back its bond issues and instead run down its
ample cash balances.
1.72 What about short-term interest rates?
Isn’t there a risk that large pay awards could
push up inflation, forcing the RBI to increase
their policy rate? As discussed above, the risk
seems small, as there’s little evidence that
public sector pay increases are transmitted to
prices, or even to wages in the private sector.
In fact, the more significant risks to inflation
would seem to be to the downside: from
lower oil prices, a slowing Chinese economy,
and the impact of fiscal deficit reduction – of
any size – on aggregate demand.
1.73
Summing up the cyclical considerations,
small differences in the degree of fiscal
adjustment may not have much impact on
interest rates. Which means that any positive
effects from a large adjustment (“austerity”)
coming from lower interest rates could
be offset by the direct negative impact on
aggregate demand.
1.74 That still leaves the second issue: the
need to put debt on a downward path. To
see whether this would be possible with a
more moderate pace of adjustment, a careful
examination of the medium-term fiscal
outlook is in order. The basic drivers of
government debt can be specified precisely.
Aside from exchange rate movements, which
are unpredictable, the evolution of the debt-
to-GDP ratio depends on two factors. These
are: (i) the level of the primary deficit, that
is, the fiscal deficit once interest costs are
set aside; and (ii) the difference between
the interest rate on government debt and the
growth of nominal GDP (multiplied by the
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
28
previous year’s debt ratio). In symbols:
d(t)- d(t-1) = p
d(t) + [i-g]/[1+g]*d(t-1)8
1.76 Put simply, primary deficits push up
the debt ratio. But nominal growth can bring
it down, as long as the growth rate exceeds
the interest rate on government debt. The
primary deficit has been curbed to less than
1 percent of GDP in 2015-16, far below the
nearly 3 percent of GDP recorded in 2011-
12. But nominal growth has collapsed, as
the GDP deflator has plunged to minimal
levels, virtually eliminating the gap between
growth and interest rates. And therein lies the
problem.
1.76 The fiscal outlook consequently hinges
on what will happen to the interest-growth
differential. If it normalizes, the debt-GDP
ratio could come down on its own, even
without adjustment measures. For example,
if nominal growth quickly recovers and
averages 12 percent over the next five years
(say, around 8 percent real and 4 percent
inflation) while the effective interest rate
on government debt stays near current
levels, then consolidated debt could fall by
1
1/2 percentage points of GDP over the next
five years – even as states assume debts of
around 2
1/2 percent of GDP under the UDAY
electricity reform scheme. Since the states
would merely be recognizing an existing
contingent liability, and bringing it onto their
own balance sheet, a better measure of the
underlying fiscal progress would perhaps
be the reduction in debt, excluding UDAY
bonds. This would be 4 percent of GDP
(Figures 13 and 14).
1.77 It would be imprudent, however, to
count on this scenario materializing. For
one thing, adverse shocks have a way of
throwing debt dynamics off course. The
global recovery could falter. Inflation could
turn out to be lower than expected. For these
or many other reasons, the interest- growth differential may not normalize anytime soon.
1.78
Consequently, a much more prudent
approach would be to assume a more gradual
recovery of nominal GDP, say one where
nominal growth averages 11 percent over
the next 5 years. In that case, the interest-
growth differential would not be sufficient
to bring down the debt—the primary deficit
would need to be reduced. But if such a
strategy were to be pursued, even modest
and gradual adjustment could eventually
make a significant difference. For example,
if the fiscal deficit were reduced annually by
around 0.2-0.3 percentage points of GDP,
by the end of the period the overall deficit
would be around 3 percent and the primary
deficit would be essentially eliminated.
Most significantly, the debt ratio would
eventually— though not immediately—fall.
Debt would decline by 2 percentage points of
GDP in overall, and 4
1/2 percentage points in
underlying terms, slightly further than in the
more favourable growth scenario (in Figure
14, this scenario would be very close to that
shown as “Debt_H”). And of course if the
economy responded to the fiscal prudence,
as well as other structural reforms being
pursued, and growth rebounded toward
earlier levels, then the debt reduction would
be even larger.
1.79 In sum, fiscal policy needs to navigate
between Scylla and Charybdis. There are very
good arguments for a strategy of aggressive
fiscal consolidation, as earlier envisaged,
and equally good arguments for a strategy
of moderate consolidation that can place the
debt on a sustainable path while avoiding
imparting a major negative demand shock
to a still-fragile recovery. The Union Budget
will carefully assess these options.
1.80 In any event, the time is ripe for a
review of the medium term fiscal framework.
A medium-term perspective to expenditure
8 d refers to public liabilities of the general government; pd refers to primary deficit; i is the interest rate and g is
the growth rate.
Economic Survey 2015-16
29
P=Projected
GDP Growth_S= Slower GDP growth forecast
GDP Growth_H= Higher GDP growth forecast
Interest rate_S= Projected interest rates under Slower GDP growth forecast
Interest rate_H= Projected interest rates under Higher GDP growth forecast
E= Estimated P=Projected
Debt_S= Debt under Slower GDP growth forecast
Debt_S_UDAY= Debt under Slower GDP growth forecast and
without UDAY
Debt_H= Debt under Higher GDP growth forecast
Debt_H_UDAY= Debt under Higher GDP growth forecast and
without UDAY E= Estimated
P=Projected
Debt_S= Debt under Slower GDP growth forecast
Debt_H= Debt under Higher GDP growth forecast
Source: CSO, RBI & projections.
Source: CSO, RBI, DMO, budget document and Projections.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
30
planning is necessary. The fundamental
growth and fiscal outlooks have changed
considerably since the Fourteenth Finance
Commission provided medium term revenue
projections. And, above all, there are new
developments in, and approaches to, medium
term fiscal frameworks around the world
from which India could usefully learn.
external outlook
1.81 Last year’s Survey had identified
a weak external environment as a major
medium- term risk. It turned out to be a short
run risk as well, and the prospects are that it
might continue to be one in the period ahead.
1.82 One of the puzzles this year has been
how remittances have held up despite a
dramatic decline in oil prices and hence in the
health of countries that host overseas Indian
workers. (Figure 15). The Indian economy
and foreign exchange earnings were buoyed
by this non-decline in remittance flows. Still,
prudence warrants monitoring this source of
earnings because it is plausible that with oil
prices remaining low in the near future, oil
exporting countries will eventually be forced
to curtail their use of foreign labour.
1.83 Overall exports declined by about 18
per cent in the first 3 quarters; much of this was due to falling commodity prices but
the decline in non-oil dollar exports and
export volume was still sizable. Exports of
commercial services remained stagnant in
the first 3 quarters compared with an average
growth of about 17 per cent during 2006-2011
(Figure 8). As a result, growth this year was
held back—by about 1-1.2 percentage points
relative to last year. A question—critical
for assessing prospects going forward—
is whether this recent export performance
is explained mainly by a decline in global
demand or a decline in competitiveness,
related to the exchange rate or other factors.
1.84 It has been well documented that at the
global level, trade has sputtered and more
so than the world GDP. So, the question is
whether India has fared worse than other
exporters.
1.85 One can answer this question by
examining how India’s exports relative to
world GDP have fared compared with world
exports. Figure 16 plots four relationships:
between India’s exports of goods and world
GDP (top left panel); between India’s export
of services and world demand (top right
panel); and the two equivalents for the world
(bottom panels). It is noteworthy that in
the 2000s, India’s exports of manufactured
Source: RBI & DGCA.
Economic Survey 2015-16
31
goods and services were above the line of
best fit but note that services outperformed
manufacturing (services data points are
more above the line than manufacturing
data points). For the world, there is a similar
but less pronounced pattern, especially for
services. In the last two years, however,
Indian services exports have been more
affected than Indian manufacturing exports
and also world service exports.
1.86 Put differently, all the focus on
manufacturing exports has distracted
attention from what might be a no less
noteworthy development. It is India’s exports
of services that has changed in the most
significant, and perhaps alarming, way. One
can see the problem looking at market shares.
India’s share of world exports of services,
after surging in the mid-2000s, has flattened
out. 1.87
What makes this development puzzling
is that in recent years the composition of
Indian exports of services is more favorable
than that of Indian exports of manufactured
goods. More of the former goes to the United
States, and more of the latter to Asia. Since
Asia has slowed down more rapidly, India’s
exports of manufactures should have been
more affected. Furthermore, in the last year,
the rupee has depreciated strongly against
the dollar which should have helped India’s
exports of services.
1.88 These developments have longer-term
implications. Realizing India’s medium
term growth potential of 8-10 per cent will
require rapid growth of exports. How rapid
this should be is suggested by comparing
India’s export performance in services with
China’s performance in manufacturing at
a comparable stage of the growth surge.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
32
Figure 17 plots China’s global market share
in manufacturing exports beginning in 1991,
and juxtaposed on it is India’s global market
share beginning in 2003 when the shares
were roughly similar. The magnitude of the
challenge becomes evident when examining
China’s trajectory over the last fifteen years.
To achieve a similar trajectory, India’s
competitiveness will have to improve so that
its services exports, currently about 3 per
cent of world exports, capture nearly 15 per
cent of world market share. That is a sizeable
challenge—and recent trends suggest that a
major effort at improving competitiveness
will be necessary to meet it.
trade PolIcy
1.89 For decades, India’s fundamental
position on trade has been common across
the political spectrum, shared by a wide
range of intellectual opinion. But during
this period the economy has changed almost
beyond recognition. The non-success of the
Nairobi WTO negotiations, the seismic shifts
in the international trade architecture because
of the emergence of mega-regional trade
agreements, and a slowing world economy
which creates pressures on domestic industry
combine to present India with a great
opportunity to collectively self-interrogate on the national near-consensus.
1.90
Introspection is overdue on five issues:
• Providing support to farmers in light of
WTO rules;
• Mitigating the impact of erratic trade
policy on farmer incentives;
• Reconciling the “big but poor” dilemma
that confronts India in trade negotiations;
• Dealing with ongoing stresses brought on
by the external environment; and
• Engaging more broadly with the world on
trade.
Agriculture and the WTO
1.91 Start first with the two key issues in
the Doha Development Agenda (DDA): the
special safeguard mechanism (SSM) and
food security/public stockholding both of
which affect farmer interests.
1.92 The SSM embodies the right to impose
trade barriers if there is a surge in agricultural
imports into India. But there is one critical
but overlooked question: to what extent
does India really need SSM? In the Uruguay
Round, many countries including India were
allowed to set ceiling (jargon for very high)
tariff bindings: that is, they were allowed to
set, as their WTO obligation, high levels of
Economic Survey 2015-16
33
tariffs which range from 40 per cent to 100
per cent (India's modal rate in agriculture)
to 150 per cent. In a preponderance of tariff
lines, there is a considerable gap between
applied tariffs and the level of tariff bindings.
1.93 Once India had this freedom, it was not
necessary to have safeguard actions because,
in response to import surges, but even
otherwise, India could raise tariffs up to the
high level of bindings. Why then, for a long
time, has India been asking for the right to
impose SSMs, which is in effect asking for
even more freedom to determine agricultural
policies?
1.94 The answer is not very clear. As Table
2 illustrates, India’s applied rate is less than 5
percent of the bound rate for about 4 percent
of tariff lines, and less than 20 percent for
about 16 percent of its tariff lines. So, India’s
only real need for SSM arises in relation
to a small fraction of its tariff lines—some
milk and dairy products, some fruits, and
raw hides—where its tariff bindings are in
the range of about 10-40 percent which can
be uncomfortably close to India’s current
tariffs, limiting India’s options in the event
of import surges. But if that is the case, India
should call for a discussion of SSMs not as a
generic issue of principle but as a pragmatic
negotiating objective covering a small
part of agricultural tariffs. Perhaps, in this
instance, lofty theologizing about freedom
and sovereignty needs to cede to mundane
haggling over hides and hibiscuses.
1.95 Take next the food security/
stockholding issue. India had obtained a
virtual cast-iron legal guarantee in 2014,
which made the Bali Decision permanent
and put it on a sound legal basis. This was re-
iterated in Nairobi. It remains open whether
pressing for “permanent solution” is vitally
necessary.
1.96 Especially at a time of farm stress,
India must have the freedom to provide
support to its farmers. The open question is its appropriate level and form. The particular
policies which are being defended are those
that India intends to move out of in any case
because of their well-documented impacts:
decline in water tables, over-use of electricity
and fertilizers (causing health harm), and
rising environmental pollution, owing to
post-harvest burning of husks. Moreover,
the government is steadfastly committed to
providing direct income support to farmers
and crop insurance which will not be
restricted by WTO rules.
1.97 The way forward on agriculture and
the WTO can be thought of in the following
conceptual terms. At the time of the Uruguay
Round, India was a net importer of food and
decided that it needed a lot of room to maintain
“border protection” (tariffs in particular) and
was less concerned about providing support
to agriculture via domestic support (producer
subsidies, minimum support prices etc). That
was India’s choice.
1.98 Twenty years on, India’s position in
agriculture has changed: it has become more
competitive in agriculture and it now relies
relatively more on domestic support (and
less on tariff protection) for agriculture both
to sustain domestic production and address
low incomes for farmers. India’s WTO
obligations could predominantly be based
on this domestic shift away from border
protection to domestic support. India could
consider offering reduction in its very high
tariff bindings and instead seek more freedom
to provide higher levels of domestic support:
this would be especially true for pulses going
forward where higher minimum support
prices may be necessary to incentivize pulses
production. This would be good for India,
and India’s trading partners should be more
reasonable about accepting this shift.
Volatile Trade Policy
1.99 Agricultural policy, especially trade
policy, is characterized by unusual volatility.
The ups and downs are striking. Take the case
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
34
of cotton shown in Table 1A in the technical
appendix of this volume. In 2010, there were
ten changes in policy, mostly relating to
exports, and often reversing previous actions.
Look at the August 4, 2011 action compared
with the action on March 31, 2011. There
were then 5 changes in 2011, 5 in 2012 and
2 in 2014.
1.100 The view is that in agriculture, the
interests of the producer and consumer have
to be balanced. When world prices go up or
there is domestic scarcity, export restrictions
or bans are imposed; when the reverse
happens, import tariffs are imposed. But this
policy volatility actually ends up hurting
farmers (of course) but eventually also
consumers. This is because farmers produce
less because of the policy volatility which
results in reduced domestic availability and
hence higher prices. Farmers are affected not
only by the fact that on average they get less
for their produce but even more so by the
policy uncertainty that dampens, even chills,
the incentive to produce. The notion that there
is a trade-off between farmers and consumers
is false except in the very short run.
1.101 Farm policy—minimum support
prices and import and export policy—should
be announced well in advance of the crop
growing season and should not be altered
during the course of the season unless there
are exceptional developments.
Broader issues: The “Big-but-Poor”
Dilemma
1.102 India also needs to address two broader
issues. The first is what might be called the
“big-but-poor” dilemma. On the one hand,
India’s self-perception as a poor country
translates into a reluctance to recognize and
practice reciprocity (give-and-take) in trade
negotiations. On the other hand, India's
policies have a significant impact on global
markets and it has become a large economy
in which partner countries have a legitimate
stake in seeking market access—just as India should in relation to its partners’ markets.
1.103 The latter means that partners expect
India to play the reciprocity game: “you
open your markets and/or you reduce your
freedom to protect in return for us doing the
same.” If the WTO is not to be consigned to
irrelevance—in the wake of the big trading
countries turning decisively away from it
towards regional agreements—there is only
one way forward: in return for similar actions
by its trading partners, India, China and other
similar countries must be willing to offer to
open up their markets and undertake greater
commitments in the context of future WTO
negotiations.
1.104 In the 1970s and 1980s, India’s
engagement in the WTO was broadly non-
reciprocal. This was possible because was small
enough for trading partners to overlook this
non-reciprocity. Today they do care because
of India’s market size, and India must respond,
balancing the “big-but-poor” dilemma.
1.105
Partner countries must show a serious
interest in reviving multilateralism. Equally
India and other emerging market economies
must make it attractive for trading partners
to engage in the WTO. An important part
of this will require India playing more of
the reciprocity game and using its growing
markets as leverage to attain its own market
interests abroad, including the mobility of
labor.
1.106 The costs of reluctant engagement
need careful review. The US and others are
negotiating agreements (the Trans-Pacific
Partnership (TPP)) that have excluded India
and hence shaped in a way that do not take
into account India’s important interests (the
rules on intellectual property are a good
illustration). If and when India joins these
agreements, it will be not on India’s terms
but on terms already cast in stone, terms that
India could not influence because of being
perceived as not engaging fully.
Economic Survey 2015-16
35
Dealing with ongoing stresses
1.107 Trade policy is under stress also for
reasons related to the ongoing turmoil in the
international environment. Global demand is
weak, and one of the powerhouses of trade
in recent times—China—is slowing down.
Chinese slowdown has important implications
for India. As the Chinese currency weakens,
setting in train reactions from other countries,
India’s external competitiveness across-the-
board will come under pressure. But there
will also be sectoral impacts. Chinese excess
capacity in commodity-related sectors such
as steel and aluminum will lead to a surge in
imports into India.
1.108 How should India respond? India
should resist calls to seek recourse in
protectionist measures, especially in
relation to items that could undermine the
competitiveness of downstream firms and
industries. India could respond in three
ways. First, the most effective instrument to
respond to threats to overall competitiveness
is the exchange rate. The rupee’s value
must be fair, avoiding strengthening. This
can be achieved through some combination
of monetary relaxation, allowing gradual
declines in the rupee if capital flows are weak,
intervention in foreign exchange markets if
inflows are robust, and being cautious about
any further opening to inflows that could
unduly strengthen the rupee.
1.109 Second, India should strengthen
procedures that allow WTO-consistent and
hence legitimate actions against dumping
(anti-dumping), subsidization (countervailing
duties), and surges in imports (safeguard
measures) to be taken expeditiously and
effectively. Ineffective domestic procedures
risk becoming the excuse for broad-based
protectionist actions. 1.110 Third, India should eliminate all the
policies that currently provide negative
protection for Indian manufacturing and
favor foreign manufacturing. This could
be achieved by quick implementation of
the GST as recommended by the recent
report of the GST Committee. If delays are
envisaged, a similar result could be achieved
by eliminating the countervailing duty
exemptions.
Broader issues: Prerequisites for Trade
opening
1.111 Underlying all these proximate
issues is a much deeper problem: can trade
liberalization be a source of efficiency,
dynamism and growth not just for services
but also agriculture and manufacturing going
forward?
1.112 To put it in the terms that Rodrik and
Subramanian (2004) used to describe India’s
reforms of the 1980s and 1990s: is India really
pro-competition or is it just pro-business?
9
1.113 Every country, and every constituency
in every country, wants more exports. But
there is much more ambivalence about
imports. The efficiency effects of trade,
however, work through imports: by exposing
domestic industry to greater competition and
by creating incentives domestically to move
resources toward export sectors.
1.114 Now, it is intrinsic to creating greater
competition that there will be churn, stress,
and dislocation, necessitating some exit of
uncompetitive firms and industries. Accepting
the transitory costs of trade liberalization
and providing a cushion against them—in
the form of targeted assistance—will be
necessary for India to be able to negotiate
credibly in the WTO today and, if India so
decides, the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
tomorrow. That is why, the government’s
9 Dani Rodrik and Arvind Subramanian, From "Hindu Growth" to Productivity Surge: The Mystery of the Indian
Growth Transition," NBER Working Paper No. 10376.
Economic Outlook, Prospects, and Policy Challenges
36
Skill India and Make in India initiatives are
so important. Greater trade opening will
increase the size of the pie but it must be
combined with assistance in the transition
phase to make everyone better off.
1.115 In some ways, that ambivalence about greater foreign competition, stemming in
turn from the domestic politics of disruption
and exit, is at the heart of India’s difficulties
with the WTO, trade agreements, and trade
policy more broadly (as discussed in Chapter
2). There is no getting away from it.
Table 2: India’s Actual and Bound Rates in Agriculture (Per cent)
Bound minus applied
No. of tariff LinesCumulative tariff Lines PercentageCumulative
0 21211.6 1.6
1-5 20411.5 3.1
6-10 13617710.4 13.5
11-20 392163.016.4
21-30 1093258.324.7
31-40 35467926.9 51.7
41-60 1117908.460.1
61-80 235102517.9 78.0
81-100 10111267.785.7
Above 100 188131414.3100.0
Total 1314
Source: WTO.
Economic Survey 2015-16
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the
Indian Economy02
IntroductIon
2.1 The Charkravyuha legend from the
Mahabharata describes the ability to enter but
not exit, with seriously adverse consequences.
It is a metaphor for the workings of the Indian
economy in the 21st century, the legacy of
several decades of economic policy making.
2.2 A market economy requires unrestricted
entry of new firms, new ideas, and new
technologies so that the forces of competition
can guide capital and labour resources to
their most productive and dynamic uses.
But it also requires exit so that resources are
forced or enticed away from inefficient and
unsustainable uses.
2.3 Joseph Schumpeter recognized the
vital role of exit, via “the gale of creative
destruction,” in the efficient workings of a
market economy, the “process of industrial
mutation that incessantly revolutionizes the
economic structure from within, incessantly
destroying the old one, incessantly creating a
new one.” 2.4
Structural impediments to India’s
economic progress have often been framed
in relation to the problem of entry as evoked
in the famous phrase--“licence-quota-permit
Raj”--of C. Rajagopalachari, India’s original
economic liberal. Since the early 1980s, the
Indian economy has made remarkable progress
in increasing entry: industrial licensing has
been dismantled, public sector monopolies
have been diluted, some public sector
assets have been privatised, foreign direct
investment has been considerably liberalised,
a process that has been accelerated under this
government, and trade barriers have been
reduced. Indeed, the narrative of reforms has
been one of promoting entry by eliminating
the barriers to it.
2.5 Yet, as this chapter will document, there
has been less progress in relation to exit. Indeed,
the twin balance sheet challenge confronting
the Indian economy today highlights vividly
the exit problem. One might, therefore, hazard
that the Indian economy had moved from
From socialism with restricted entry to “marketism” without exit
India has made great strides in removing the barriers to the entry of firms,
talent, and technology into the Indian economy. Less progress has been made in
relation to exit. Thus, over the course of six decades, the Indian economy moved
from ‘socialism with limited entry to “marketism” without exit’. Impeded exit
has substantial fiscal, economic, and political costs. We document its pervasive
nature which encompasses not just the public sector and manufacturing but the
private sector and agriculture. A number of solutions to facilitate exit are possible.
The government’s initiatives including the new bankruptcy law, rehabilitation of
stalled projects, proposed changes to the Prevention of Corruption Act as well
as the broader JAM agenda hold the promise of facilitating exit, and providing a
significant boost to long-run efficiency and growth.
CHAPTER
38
socialism with restricted entry to “marketism”
without exit.
2.6 To be sure, in a country as large and
diverse as India, exit may not always be
desirable. But policy action is needed when
the costs clearly outweigh the benefits,
when the lack of exit generates externalities
that hurt others—such as firms that have to
compete with subsidised “sick” firms or
taxpayers who have to pay for the corporate
subsidies. Those paying the costs could well
be the poor. They pay taxes, even if only
indirect ones. And they may also have to
bear the burden of paying higher prices while
getting substandard goods and services from
inefficient firms which should have exited,
but haven’t. In fact, the true beneficiaries of
the interventions that prevent exit may often
be the rich, who own the firms.
2.7 Two caveats are in order. First, focusing
on the exit problem does not mean that the
challenges of entry have been fully addressed.
The Government’s reform agenda, including
liberalising FDI and launching the Start-up
India and Entrepreneurship initiatives are
noteworthy endeavours to further facilitate
entry.
2.8 Second, there are sectors in which exit is not a first-order problem, for example IT
services and e-commerce, evidenced most
recently in the dynamism displayed in relation
to start-ups in India. The case studies suggest
that the Chakravyuha challenge is more a
feature of the relatively traditional sectors of
the economy but is not restricted to the public
sector—indeed, impeded exit in the private
sector is becoming a major challenge.
2.9
The chapter is divided into four sections.
In the next section we briefly describe the
costs of impeded exit. In subsequent sections
we illustrate costs of impeded exit and the
severity and breadth of the problem with
sectoral examples. We then place them into
analytical categories that explain why exit is
difficult. And, finally, in the last section, we
provide tentative solutions for facilitating
greater exit.
Magn Itude of the Proble M
2.10 That there is an exit problem in
India is beyond dispute. But how severe
is the problem? There are several ways of
answering the question. Figure 1 below
provides one measure, based on the size of
firms. In principle, productive and innovative
firms should expand and grow, forcing out the
Source: Hsieh and Klenow (2014).
Figure 1: Average employment of old and
new plants in India, Mexico and US Figure 2: Average employment of old and
new plants in India, FY1999 and FY2010
Economic Survey 2015-16
39
unproductive ones. So surviving firms should
be much larger than new ones. Figure 1 shows
that in the US the average 40-year old plant
is 8 times larger (in terms of employment)
than a new one. Established Mexican firms
are twice as large as new firms. But in 2010
India the average 40 year old plant was only
1.5 times larger than a new one.
2.11 Figure 2 illustrates the situation has
worsened over the years. It plots the size of
Indian plants relative to new ones across their
ages from the Annual Survey of Industries in
1998-99 and 2009-10; in 1998-99 the ratio
was 2.5. But now the gap between old and
new firms is much smaller. Taken together,
these charts show that there are not enough
big firms and too many firms that are unable
to grow, the latter suggesting that there are
problems of exit.
2.12 Bloom and Van Reenen (2010)
1 take
another approach. They show that India
unlike many countries seems to have a
disproportionately large share of inefficient
firms with very low productivity and with
little exit. They assign a management practice
scores of 1 to 5 (worst to best) for a sample
of 695 randomly chosen U.S. manufacturing
firms with 100 to 5,000 employees and the
second panel for 620 similarly sized Indian
ones. The results reveal that compared to
the US, there is a “thick tail” of badly run
firms in India. This is directly related to an
exit problem in Indian industry because a
majority of these large numbers of small and
inefficient firms should not survive.
costs of IMP eded ex It
2.13 Why does the situation matter? The
lack of exit creates at least three types of
costs: fiscal, economic (or opportunity), and
political.
2.14 Fiscal costs: Exit is impeded often
through government support of incumbent, mostly inefficient, firms. This support—in
the form of explicit subsidies (for example.
bailouts) or implicit ones (tariffs, loans
from state banks)—represents a cost to the
economy. The cost is an increasing function of
the taxes that will have to make up for the lost
revenue, and/or the general equilibrium effects
of greater deficits, via the greater interest
costs and reduced private sector investment
activity that result if the government borrows
to finance the foregone revenue.
2.15
Economic costs: Economic losses result
from resources and factors of production not
being employed in their most productive
uses. In a capital scarce country such as
India, misallocation of resources can have
significant costs. In their study, Hsieh and
Klenow ("Misallocation and Manufacturing
TFP in China and India", The Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 2009)
argue that
when capital and labour are hypothetically
reallocated within firms to equalize marginal
products to the extent observed in the United
States, it leads to manufacturing TFP gains of
40 – 60 per cent in India. Now, not all of this
misallocation is due to impeded exit but that
does play an important role in impeding the
needed reallocation of resources.
2.16 Another cost, in the current context,
stems from the overhang of stressed assets on
corporate and bank balance sheets. It reflects
the difficulty of apportioning costs of past
mistakes between equity holders, creditors,
taxpayers and consumers. The consequence is
a reduced flow of new investment, dampening
medium term growth.
2.17 Political costs: The lack of exit can
also have considerable political costs for
governments attempting to reform the
economy. The benefits of impeded exit
often flow to the rich and influential in the
form of support for "sick" firms. This can
give the impression that governments favour
1 Bloom, N. & John van Reenen, 2010, “Why do Management Practices Differ across Firms and Countries?”
Journal of Economic Perspectives.
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the Indian Economy
40
large corporates, which politically limits the
ability to undertake measures that will benefit
the economy but might be seen as further
benefitting business. Similarly, if wilful
defaulters cannot be dealt with appropriately,
the legitimacy of a market economy and the
regulating institutions can themselves be
called into question.
2.18 No sector illustrates the combination
of fiscal, economic, and political costs more
starkly than fertilizer. As shown in Chapter
9, fiscal subsidies amount to 0.8percent
of GDP, much of which leaks abroad or to
non-agricultural uses, or goes to inefficient
producers, or to firms given the exclusive
privilege to import. But precisely for these
reasons it has proved politically impossible
to close the inefficient firms or eliminate the
canalisation of imports. 2.19
While recognising the centrality of
low cost fertilisers for all farmers, big and
small it should be noted that the subsidy to
farmers—which predominantly benefits
large farmers-cannot be reduced/eliminated
because of an exit problem- the entitlement
that farmers, especially rich farmers, have
internalised, and the power of their voice in
preventing reform. In order to maintain low
domestic prices to farmers (the consumer
subsidy), both producers and importers have
to be subsidised. But eliminating the producer
subsidy runs up against the exit problem in
relation to inefficient producers. Eliminating
canalization could face resistance from
existing importers and so on.
2.20 Nor is agriculture immune from the
exit problem evidenced in the persistence of
policies that promote some crops that create
Table 1: Characterising the Exit Problem
Sector Employment Inefficiency Measure/Cost2Solution
PUBLIC SECTOR
Fertilizers (inefficient firms) 15,619
Estimated subsidy based on economic
cost of production Rs. 23,013 crore in 2013-14 . Progress being made with neem-coating
which reduces diversion, decanalisation, JAM for farmers (Chapter 3).
Civil Aviation 25,047
3 In 2013-14, the total loss was about
Rs. 2400 crore; 7th straight year of loss Strategic approach.
Public Sector Banks (a few banks) 86,744
Capital infusion between 2009-10 and
2015-16 (H1): Rs. 1.02 lakh crore. Consolidate; Strategically disinvest;
4 R’s for the NPA problem: Recognition,
Recapitalization, Resolution and Reform
(Chapter 1).Changing PCA (Box 2.2)
Discoms
(major loss-making states) 2.6 lakh
Accumulated losses over 2008-09 and
2013-14 about Rs. 2.3 lakh crores. Tying structural improvements with debt
relief (as in UDAY). Create ‘one market’ in power (Chapter 11).
Central Public Sector Enterprises 2.5 lakh
(sick CPSEs, 2013-14) Accumulated losses of sick units as of
2013-14: Rs 1.04 lakh crore. Allow sick CPSEs to exit. Leverage the
land and capital unlocked to promote new investment.
Administrative Schemes N/A
Number of central sector and centrally
sponsored schemes increased from
908 in 2006-07 to 1086 in 2014-15. Rationalisation of schemes as done in
2014-15. Regular evaluations.
Regulatory bodies N/AThe average age of their heads is about
60. Administrative reform to bring in young,
professional talent.
PRIVATE SECTOR
Agriculture (cereals and sugar) N/A
Over-intensive cultivation of water-
intensive crops has led to water tables declining at a rate of 0.3 meters per year. Incentivize pulses over water-guzzling
crops. Facilitate use of drip irrigation
(chapters 3 and 4). Highlight social costs and benefits of crop production.
2 Unless otherwise specified, numbers are inflation-adjusted.
3 Air India Annual Report 2012-13.
Economic Survey 2015-16
41
Table 1: Characterising the Exit Problem
SectorEmployment Inefficiency Measure/Cost2Solution
Steel N/ACost of production 50-75% higher for
few inefficient firms in comparison to global norms. Bankruptcy Code.
Infrastructure
(few large groups) N/A
As of FY15 the average interest cover
is about 0.3. Kelkar (PPP) Committee
recommendations, bankruptcy code. Changing PCA (Box 2.2 below)
Small Savings N/AImplicit subsidy to well-off:
Rs 11,900 crore. Rationalize schemes to benefit the
small savers. Make transparent true beneficiaries (chapter 6).
ECONOMY WIDE
Trade Liberalisation N/ANearly highest restrictions on imports;
gains from liberalisation of goods and services estimated at 1% of GDP
4.
Safety nets to tackle transitory costs of greater trade liberalization and competition (chapter 1).
Labour N/ANot enough big firms and too many
small and inefficient firms (Hsieh
& Klenow, [2014]
5; Bloom and van
Reenen [2010]). Employee-centric regulations; provision
of greater choice to employees (chapter 10).
adverse externalities at the expense of others;
nor is it the case that impeded exit benefits
the poor because the relatively well-off are
also beneficiaries of the interventions that
prevent exit.
descrIb Ing the Proble M of ex It
2.21 An exhaustive documentation and
quantification of the exit problem is difficult.
We will instead illustrate the problem by a
partial listing. In what follows, we cite and
briefly discuss (Box 2.1) instances where exit
has emerged as a serious constraint.
2.22 There are many ways to measure the
exit problem. For the sake of simplicity and
consistency, we use some simple metrics. These are presented in Table 1. For each
case, it presents a measure of employment,
inefficiency and potential solutions.
2.23
Box 2.1 also documents in greater
detail the exit problem for certain specific
sectors listed in Table 1: public sector banks,
infrastructure, steel and trade.
Why is There an Exit Problem?
2.24 It is useful to understand the exit
problem in terms of analytical categories
because it aids in the search for solutions.
In India, the exit problem arises because of
three types of reasons, what might be called
the three I’s: interests, institutions, and ideas/
ideology .
Box 2.1: Characteristics of Selected Sectors
I. Public Sector Banks
The first figure reports the bank-wise time series of return on assets (RoA) which are declining rapidly across
the banking landscape. There is a corresponding deterioration in the asset portfolio the full extent of which will
be known after the RBI completes its asset quality review. The second figure plots the return on assets against
employment for all public sector banks.
6 The lines represent median values. The RoA for most banks is currently
less than one third of the norm of 1 per cent that is considered reasona\
ble.7 Many, though not all, of the less
profitable banks are those with smaller levels of employment.
4 The World Bank. http://www.wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/WDSP/
IB/2015/03/10/090224b082bf51e6/1_0/Rendered/PDF/Economic0impli0nd0the0Un\
ited0States.pdf
5 Klenow, P & Chang-Tai Hsieh, 2014. “The Life Cycle of Plants in India and Mexico”, The Quarterly Journal of
Economics.
6 Note that State Bank of India and Punjab National Bank are not included- they are two largest employers. 7 Most private sector banks currently in India have a RoA of more than 1 per cent.
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the Indian Economy
42
Source: Credit Suisse.
II. Infrastructure and Corporate Performance
Corporate balance sheets are stretched,
depressing private investment. In the Economic
Survey 2014-15, we called it the “balance
sheet syndrome with Indian characteristics.”
The figure below provides a scatter plot of debt
to equity ratios against interest coverage ratios
(ICR) of the 10 most overstretched corporate
groups according to the latest data from Credit
Suisse. An ICR of less than 2.5 is considered
quite low- it implies that the revenues are not
sufficient to cover the interest costs on debt.
III. Steel
The steel sector is under severe stress for
domestic and international reasons. The figure
below shows that the cost of production of a
few private players (5 and 6) for FY15 is significantly greater than that of other firms when benchmarked against
international prices.
Source: Reserve Bank of India (RBI).
Economic Survey 2015-16
43
IV. Trade
The last figure of the box shows that India has amongst the severest trade restrictions in goods (y-axis) and
services (x-axis). Only Brazil has higher manufacturing tariffs, China and Indonesia more severe restrictions
on services trade. This ambivalence about greater foreign competition owes in part to the domestic politics of
disruption and exit, and might be at the heart of India’s difficulties with the WTO, trade agreements, and trade
policy more broadly.
2.25 Interests: The first, most obvious, and
perhaps most powerful reason for lack of
exit is the power of vested interests. Often,
this vested interest problem is aggravated
by a certain imbalance or asymmetry (first
identified by the Italian economist Pareto) that confers greater power on concentrated
producer interests in relation to diffused
consumer interests. It has long been known
that trade liberalization is difficult because the
beneficiaries are consumers (whose aggregate
benefit is large but who benefit individually
Source: Credit Suisse.
Source: World Bank.
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the Indian Economy
44
by a small amount) and the losers are a few
producers each of whom stands to lose by a
lot. The latter will be more influential because
they have more voice, backed by financial
power. And often democratic political
systems will give disproportional influence
to the latter.
2.26 One good example of interest groups
blocking reform comes from introducing
JAM for MGNREGA expenditure. It is
acknowledged that MGNREGA, despite its
benefits as a well-targeted social insurance
mechanism and for rural development,
suffers from significant leakage. To reduce
leakages and payment delays, Andhra Pradesh
introduced direct benefit transfers, so that
salaries would be paid directly to workers,
with biometric Smartcards to reduce the
scope of siphoning of funds via registering
ghost workers.
2.27 The Smartcards program was a
tremendous success, reducing payment
delays by 19 per cent, increasing MGNREGA
wages by 24 per cent and reducing leakages
by 35 per cent. The return on investing in
Smartcards infrastructure was thus seven
times the cost of implementation. 90 per cent
of beneficiaries also preferred the Smartcards
system (Muralidharan et. al. 2015)
8. And yet,
the perception was created that the program
was mostly negative. This was a classic
case of the imbalance of power between
concentrated losses and diffuse benefits.
2.28 In the case of administrative schemes,
vested interests often create a market of their
own, planning their actions to benefit from it:
put differently, this is a case of supply creating
its own demand. Thus schemes may become an instrument of granting favours. Finally,
bureaucratic inertia perpetuates persistence.
Figure 3 plots the cumulative distribution
function of Central Sector Schemes that were
allocated money as per the Union Budget
2015-16
9. It shows the percentage of schemes
by their longevity. For example, 50 percent
of schemes were 25 years old. And out of
the 104 total schemes, 92 have been ongoing
for 15 years or more.
10 Longevity, per se,
may not be a problem but extra vigilance
is necessary to ensure that schemes remain
relevent and useful over time. And vigilance
should probably increase in proportion to the
longevity of schemes.
8 Muralidharan, K., Paul Niehaus & S. Sukhtankar, 2015, "Building State Capacity: Evidence from Biometric
Smartcards in india", J-PAL.
9 Note that Central Sector Schemes are different (and less in number) than Centrally Sponsored Schemes.
The major difference is that the former is funded entirely by the Central government and implemented by
its machinery, whereas the latter is based on subjects in the State List, and is majorly funded by the Central
government but implemented by the states.
10 There is scheme that is 96 years old called 'Livestock Health & Disease Control' under the Department of
Animal Husbandry, Dairying and Fisheries. In the Union Budget 2015-16, it was allocated R 251 crores.
Source: Ministry of Finance.
2.29 Institutions: Another reason for
impeded exit is institutions. The interesting,
even paradoxical, fact about India today is
that the problem arises from a combination
of both weak and strong institutions.
2.30 Examples of weak institutions are legal
procedures that increase the costs—time and
financial costs—of exit. One example is the
Economic Survey 2015-16
45
debt recovery tribunals (DRTs). As the name
suggests, they perform the role of helping
financial institutions recover bad debt quickly
and efficiently. In principle, both banks and
borrowers can approach the DRTs to settle
outstanding debt repayment problems.
2.31 With rising non-performing assets,
recourse to DRTs has increased dramatically.
Figure 4 shows that the share of settled cases
is small and declining; and the accumulated
backlog of unsettled cases increased to nearly
Rs. 4 lakh crore at the end of FY15.
2.32 The delay in debt recovery creates
dynamic efficiency cost on the economy
since it prevents the cleaning up of balance
sheets of banks and the corporate sector.
2.33 Another stark example of weak
institutions is simply the inability to
punish wilful defaulters: if demonstrable
wrongdoing goes unpunished, the legitimacy
of all institutions is called into question.
2.34 Paradoxically in India, exit is also
impeded by “strong” institutions. For a
number of reasons, certain institutions—
characterized by Devesh Kapur of University
of Pennsylvania as “referee institutions”-
-for example, some of our investigative institutions have become enormously
powerful over the last few decades. The
strength of these institutions now exists in
conjunction with another feature of Indian
decision-making, namely the asymmetric
incentives for bureaucrats that favours
abundant caution and hence the status quo.
2.35
One consequence of this is that
incentives are stacked against decisions to
precipitate exit. In the case of public sector
banks, it is well-known that senior managers
are often reluctant to take decisions to write
down loans for fear of being seen as favouring
corporate interests and hence susceptible to
scrutiny. This encourages ever-greening of
loans, postponing exit. (see Box 2.2 for an
analysis and possible solution).
2.36 Consider the difficulty. On the one hand,
a market economy requires the operation of
the perpetrator pays principle (PPP). If equity
providers/promoters take risks that do not pay
off, they must pay the financial consequences:
that is at the heart of limited liability in a
market economy, and bankruptcy procedures
enshrine this principle. Otherwise, perverse
incentives—the problem of moral hazard—
are created.
Source: Ministry of Finance.
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the Indian Economy
46
2.37 On the other hand, though,
circumstances may demand that the PPP be
applied with less than full vigour. In the case of
India, ten large corporate houses account for
a sizable share of private capital expenditure.
Penalising them might lead to the destruction
of assets which might otherwise be amenable
to rehabilitation. Tricky trade-offs must be
made between the perpetrator pays principle
and the need to revive investment in a weak
economy. But the Damocles sword of “strong
referee institutions” -- undoubtedly critical for
any democracy -- militates against nuanced,
even risky, decision-making when departures
from strict principles may be necessary.
2.38 Ideas/Ideology: A third reason for
impeded exit relates to ideas/ideology. All
around the world, and at most points in time,
it is very difficult to phase out entitlements.
But this may be especially true in a country
with sizable poverty and inequality and
one that is a democracy. Democracy will
favour—legitimately—redistribution for the
numerous poor. The founding ideology of
state-led development and socialism both
mirrored this imperative and furthered the
objective.
2.39 A good illustration arises in relation
to all the interventions in agriculture and
all the anti-poverty programs. The objective
in all these cases is laudable. But once the
policies and programs have been set in place,
they are very difficult to reverse. Minimum
support prices (MSPs) were envisioned as an
insurance mechanism for farmers, but have
become price floors instead, favouring some
crops in some regions at the expense of others.
A variety of subsidies and tax concessions
are intended for the poor end up accruing
to the relatively better-off (see Chapter 6).
The political communication of targeting
and policies that promote it are evidently not
easy.
2.40 Another factor that impedes exit is
what might be called the “sanctification of the small.” To be sure, small firms and enterprises
merit help through easy availability of credit.
It is equally true that economic dynamism
and long-run growth requires small firms
becoming big and efficient. The experience
of the infrastructure boom in which big
corporate groups were serial perpetrators
should not result in the “sanctification of the
small.”
conclus
Ion: address Ing the Proble M
2.41 How might the exit problem be
addressed? At least, five possible ways
suggest themselves.
2.42 Avoid exit through liberal entry:
Since 1991, an overarching principle for
eliminating inefficiency and/or addressing
the exit problem in vast parts of the economy
has been this: to promote competition via
private sector entry rather than change
ownership through privatisation. This
approach had some intrinsic merit - after
all, Russia suffered from trying to privatize
assets which ended up in the hands of a few
so-called “oligarchs.”
2.43 More importantly, the entry-favouring
approach had the virtue of political
expediency. Achieving exit via privatising
public sector companies would have
encountered significant opposition from
their managers as well as labour interests.
Allowing private sector companies to enter
the market without touching the public
sector incumbents bypassed some of these
costs. The logic, of course, was that a vibrant
private sector would grow rapidly.
2.44 And the strategy broadly worked.
The Indian aviation and telecommunication
sectors of today are unrecognizably different
from what they were 20 years ago, with
enormous benefits for the citizens. Public
sector companies now account for a small
share of the overall size of these sectors. In
some ways, the exit problem has been skirted
if not avoided.
Economic Survey 2015-16
47
2.45 In the financial sector, liberal entry of
more banks and different types of banks and
entry into capital markets still remains an
option to shrink the role of inefficient public
sector banks.
2.46 Direct policy action: Some of the
problems of weak institutions can be
addressed through better laws. This is why the
government has introduced a new bankruptcy
law that will significantly expedite exit (see
Appendix for salient features of the draft
Bankruptcy Code submitted to Parliament).
2.47 Similarly, part of the problem arising
from overly strong institutions can be
addressed by empowering bureaucrats and
reducing their vulnerability. One way, which
the government is actively considering, is
to reform the Prevention of Corruption Act,
differentiating cases of graft from those of
genuine errors of decision-making (see Box
2.2).
2.48 The exit problem in relation to public-
private partnership projects requires the
creation of alternative, albeit temporary,
structures to be able to credibly allocate the
burden of past failure. The Kelkar Committee
on “Revisiting and Revitalising the Public
Private Partnership model of Infrastructure”
has made recommendations on resolving
legacy issues and key contractual features
going forward. The Committee has
recommended quick finalisation of principles
of renegotiation to build in the flexibility
while protecting authorities against the risk of
moral hazard. Recognizing the importance of
predictability and fairness in dealing with both
sides of the partnership, the Committee has
recommended the setting up of independent
sector regulators with a unified mandate.
2.49 Technology and the JAM solution:
Many of the exit problems—in relation to
fertilizer, agriculture, sugar etc—can be
addressed through technology and leveraging
the potential of JAM. DBT in fertilizer and
other input use can achieve targeting which allows the poor to be protected while allowing
the underlying and persistent distortions to be
removed.
2.50
Technology can help in two ways.
First, it brings down human discretion and
the layers of intermediaries. And, second,
it breaks the old shackles and old ways of
doing business. Both can contribute directly
to finding solutions to the exit problems
plaguing Indian agriculture and informal
sectors (Chapter 3 discusses these solutions
in greater detail).
2.51 Transparency: In relation to agriculture,
the government sets minimum support prices
to create incentives for producing wheat,
cereals, and pulses. It is increasingly clear
that there is over-production of cereals,
especially in some states. Reducing this
over-production—a manifestation of this exit
problem—is difficult. But one possible way
of effecting change it to throw light on the
costs of the status quo.
2.52 One possibility might be for the
government to highlight the social costs of
producing cereals in the north-western states:
over-use of fertilizer and the health and soil
quality costs; over-use of water and power and
the environmental costs; and the post-harvest
burning of stalks that leads to pollution and
health hazards. For pulses, the social and
economic accounting should include the
benefits that their cultivating creates in the
form of better fixing nitrogen and efficient
use of fertiliser and water. The Commission
for Agricultural Costs and Prices (CACP),
for example, could publish these social
costs and benefits of production along with
its routine calculation of the private costs of
production.
2.53 Another example relates to the “small”
savings schemes. Here, transparency about
the real beneficiaries—identified in Chapter
6 as the very rich and not the “small” at all—
can help further reform and facilitate exit.
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the Indian Economy
48
2.54 Exit as an opportunity: In many
cases where public sector firms need to be
privatized, the problems of exit arise because
of opposition from existing managers
or employees’ interests. But in some
instances, such action can be converted into
opportunities. For example, resources earned
from privatization could be earmarked for
employee compensation and retraining.
2.55 Most public sector firms occupy
relatively large tracts of land in desirable
locations. Parts of this land can be converted
into land banks and made into vehicles for
promoting the 'Make in India' and Smart City campaigns. If the land is in dense urban areas,
it could be used to develop eco-systems to
nurture start-ups and if located in smaller
towns and cities, it could be used to develop
sites for industrial clusters.
2.56
One concern with privatization is the
fear that social policies—of reservation for
example—will become casualties when the
underlying assets move from public sector
to private sector control. Credibly ensuring
that such policies will be maintained will be
necessary to secure wider social acceptability
for exit.
Box 2.2: Improving economic policy-making and implementation by getting public servants to decide without fear or favour
Rapid and equitable economic growth requires the formulation and implementation of good policy, which in
turn involves both ministers and civil servants. There is a widely held perception, both within the civil service
and among outsiders who interact with government, that civil servants have in recent times become increasingly
reluctant to decide issues quickly and firmly. This has consequences for the economy.
The problems with civil service decision-making stem from multiple sources. Firstly, there are gaps in capacity,
training and specialised knowledge in dealing with certain kinds of economic issues. Secondly, the increasing
number and rigour of external oversight mechanisms may have unintended effects. As Prendergast
11 and Kapur12
have argued, external monitoring in the public sector tends to be skewed towards bad decisions that were taken
rather than good decisions that were not taken (i.e. opportunities that were missed). This promotes a culture
where avoidance of mistakes is more important than the pursuit of opportunities. However this box will focus on
the third and possibly most important reason which may also be the easiest to remedy: certain provisions of the
anti-corruption law and the way they have been used in recent years.
Good public administration and sound policy making requires that public servants take decisions in public interest
and, in particular, without ‘fear or favour’ (a phrase which finds place in the oath of office for ministers). There
is a credible perception that well-intentioned but draconian legal provisions seeking to prevent decision making
with favour, seem to be resulting in decision taking with fear. Some provisions of anti-corruption law seem to
scare the honest without deterring the corrupt.
The Prevention of Corruption Act
In a bid to tighten anti-corruption law, the new Prevention of Corruption Act of 1988
13 (PCA) added a provision
in Section 13(1)(d)(iii) according to which:
A public servant is said to commit the offence of criminal misconduct if he, while holding office as a public
servant, obtains for any person any valuable thing or pecuniary advantage without any public inter est.
Because the definition does not include words like ‘corruptly’ or ‘wrongfully’, this offence has no requirement of
mens rea or guilty intent – it is an 'absolute offence'. Since the law does not require the public servant to have had
any improper motive, even a benefit conferred inadvertently is sufficient to be prosecuted. For example, suppose
an honest public servant makes, in good faith, an error of judgment and undervalues an asset which is being
disinvested. Obviously that undervaluation causes a pecuniary gain to the buyer of the asset and is not in public
interest, but it was not a corrupt or deliberate undervaluation. Indeed it may not even have been appeared at the
11 Prendergast, C., 2001, "Selection and Oversight in the Public Sector", NBER Working Paper No. 8664,
12 Kapur, Devesh, 2003, "Do As I Say Not As I Do: A Critique of G-7 Proposals on Reforming the Multilateral
Development Banks", United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, G-24 Discussion Paper Series.
13 http://www.persmin.gov.in/DOPT/EmployeesCorner/Acts_Rules/PCAct/pcact.pdf
Economic Survey 2015-16
49
time of the decision to be an error of judgment. An error (with no benefit to the public servant), or something
regarded with hindsight as an error, can constitute a crime punishable by imprisonment and, during the trial
stage, the stigma of corruption. No such section appears to exist in other democracies, where it is the duty of the
investigating agencies to establish corruption including evidence of mot\
ive and thus mens rea.
Is public interest served by this approach?
Wrongdoing by public servants can fall in a continuum ranging from receiving minor non-monetary benefits
to outright bribery. The purpose behind Section 13(1)(d)(iii) was to provide a catch-all offence to deal with
difficult cases where a public servant could confer favours without leaving any trail. Since other provisions
of law specifically deal with a wide range of corruption offences covering every form of ‘illicit gratification’,
Section 13 (1)(d)(iii) essentially targets minor forms of corruption (by diluting the standard of proof). It is meant
to make it easier for Indian investigative agencies to prosecute for corruption without having to establish any
direct benefit to the decision-taker or participant in a decision.
In tackling corruption, two kinds of error may arise- Type I error where the corrupt may escape, and Type II
error where an innocent person may be falsely accused of corruption. An extremist approach to reducing Type
I errors by preventing the escape of those who may have received minor or non-monetary favours, or against
whom proof of illicit gratification cannot be found, increases the chance of a Type II error where an innocent
person (who took decisions with no ulterior motives) is prosecuted.
From an economic point of view, the loss to the public from the Type II error and the policy and implementation
paralysis it promotes, is far larger. This draconian section therefore appears to be hurting the public more t\
han
it has helped it. There is considerable and very credible evidence that many serious governance problems--the
reluctance of government to accept responsibility for its own delays in projects, the penchant for departments to
appeal even fair and reasonable arbitration awards or lower court judgements, the tendency to raise tax disputes
based on audit objections even if the tax authority disagrees with the auditor, the reluctance of civil servants
to sell land or divest public enterprises--are traceable in large part to the fear of ‘causing pecuniary gain’ to the
other side.
Remedies
Amendments to the PCA
The Prevention of Corruption (Amendment) Bill 2013
14 , which is pending in the Rajya Sabha, seeks to carry out
major improvements to the PCA and in general strengthen the anti-corruption law by bringing it into conformity
the United Nations Convention against Corruption. It proposes to replace the provisions of Section 13(1) with
new wording in conformity with international norms that is fairer and would prevent prosecution for mere
administrative errors. The Kelkar Committee on Public Private Partnerships too has strongly recommended
amendment of the law to protect bona fide decision-making.
Commission to recommend a new prosecutorial approach
The combination of Section 13(1)(d)(iii) PCA and Section 120A of the Indian Penal Code may have rendered
prosecuting agencies ‘lazy’ in the figurative sense of not needing to do the painstaking forensic and investigative
work needed to trace the money flow of bribes and establish pecuniary gain. Experience with successful
prosecution of white collar crime in developed countries suggests that Indian investigative agencies may need to
change their approach and modernize their investigative techniques. Many staff of the investigative agencies do
not have the tools, skills or training to do a proper investigation of modern day financial crime and corruption.
It would be desirable for the Government to set up a Commission to recommend a new prosecutorial policy for
the offence of corruption which balances the need for probity with the need for bona fide decisions to be taken
without fear of false allegations of corruption. The Commission should also recommend measures to improving
the capacity of both the investigative agencies and the public prosecutors. It is crucial that the Commission have
the resources needed to access international expertise.
Re-assess the relevance of the Vigilance machinery
The Government and public sector are dotted with a large number of ‘Vigilance Officers’. Quantitative evidence
and public perception both suggest that this has not been accompanied by any reduction in levels of corruption,
and if anything the problem is perceived to have worsened. The Vigilance Officer system is widely felt to be
ineffective and in some cases even counter-productive. It may be time to consider whether the costs of this
elaborate, but apparently ineffective, system are worthwhile.
14 http://www.prsindia.org/administrator/uploads/general/1376983957~~PCA%20Bill%202013.pdf
The Chakravyuha Challenge of the Indian Economy
Spreading JAM across India’s
economy03
IntroductIon
3.1 Cash transfers can directly improve
the economic lives of India’s poor, and raise
economic efficiency by reducing leakages
and market distortions. Implementing direct
benefit transfers (DBT) at large-scale and in
real-time remains one of the government’s key
objectives, and significant progress has been
made in the past year. Last year’s Economic
Survey explained how the JAM Trinity—Jan
Dhan, Aadhaar, Mobile—can help government
implement DBTs. This chapter:
• Takes stock of the spread of JAM;
• Studies the government’s first full- scale cash transfer program – delivering
cooking gas (LPG) subsidies via DBT;
• Discusses first-mile, middle-mile and last-
mile issues to help policymakers decide
where next to spread JAM;
• Presents a simple JAM preparedness
index to assess states’ ability to implement
two varieties of JAM—DBT and Aasaan;
and
• Concludes with policy recommendations
on LPG and the broader JAM agenda.
the Ingred Ients of Jam
3.2 Suppose the government wanted to
Large-scale, technology-enabled, real-time Direct Benefit Transfers can improve the
economic lives of India’s poor, and the JAM Trinity—Jan Dhan, Aadhaar, Mobile—can
help government implement them. Over the past year JAM has thickened and spread:
Jan Dhan and Aadhaar deepened their coverage at an astonishing rate—respectively
creating 2 and 4 million accounts per week—and several mobile money operators
were licensed. This chapter examines the first variety of JAM—the PAHAL scheme
of transferring LPG subsidies via DBT. The scheme reduced leakages by 24 per cent
and seems to have excluded few genuine beneficiaries. When deciding where next
to spread JAM, policymakers should consider first-mile (beneficiary identification),
middle-mile (distributor opposition) and last-mile (beneficiary financial inclusion)
challenges. Our JAM preparedness index suggests that the main constraint on JAM’s
spread is the last-mile challenge of getting money from banks into people’s hands,
especially in rural areas. The government should improve financial inclusion by
developing banking correspondent and mobile money networks, while in the interim
considering models like BAPU—Biometrically Authenticated Physical Uptake.
At present, the most promising targets for JAM are fertiliser subsidies and within-
government fund transfers—areas under significant central government control and
with substantial potential for fiscal savings.
CHAPTER
51
transfer R1000 to every Indian tomorrow. What
would that require?
1. Government must be able to identify
beneficiaries;
2. Government must be able to transfer
money to beneficiaries;
3. Beneficiaries must be able to easily access
theirs money.
3.3 Failure on (1) leads to inclusion errors
and leakage – benefits intended for the poor
flow to rich and “ghost” households, resulting
in fiscal loss. Failure on (2) and (3) leads to
exclusion errors – genuine beneficiaries being
unable to avail benefits. The government
must be especially sensitive to exclusion errors, which typically hurt the poorest and
can be invoked as reason—and highlighted
by leakage beneficiaries—to roll back DBT
schemes1. We now discuss the 3 requirements
for JAM in turn.
Government → Beneficiary: the challenge
of identification
3.4 To identify beneficiaries, the
government needs databases of eligible
individuals. Beneficiary databases have
existed for long before Aadhaar, but their
accuracy and legitimacy have been hampered
by the administrative and political discretion
involved in granting identity proofs like BPL
cards, driving licenses and voter IDs. Ghost
and duplicate names crept into beneficiary
lists, leading to leakage. Aadhaar’s virtue
lies in using technology to replace human
discretion, while keeping the system simple
enough – fingerprints and iris scans – for
citizens to understand.
3.5 The current government has built on
the previous government’s support for the
Aadhaar program: 210 million Aadhaar cards
were created in 2015, at an astonishing rate
of over 4 million cards per week. 975 million
1 Even in one of the most successful DBT programs—MGNREGA in Andhra Pradesh, which had 92 percent
customer satisfaction rates
—the feedback that bubbled up to top administrators through the state bureaucracy
was disproportionately negative. This was a classic case of large, diffuse benefits and small but concentrated
losses (Muralidharan et al 2015).
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
52
2 Jan Dhan was awarded a Guinness World record for opening the most bank accounts in a single week (18 million
during 23-29 August 2014).
individuals now hold an Aadhaar card – over
75 percent of the population and nearly 95
per cent of the adult population (Figure 1).
Figure 2 shows that Aadhaar penetration
is high across states. Nearly one-third of
all states have coverage rates greater than
90 percent; and only in 4 states—Nagaland
(48.9), Mizoram (38.0), Meghalaya (2.9) and
Assam (2.4)—is penetration less than 50 per
cent.
Government → Bank: the challenge of
payment
3.6 After identifying beneficiaries, the
government must transfer money to them.
Every beneficiary needs a bank account and the government needs their account numbers.
This constraint has been significantly eased
by the Pradhan Mantri Jan Dhan Yojana,
under whose auspices nearly 120 million
accounts were created in the last year alone—
at a blistering, record-setting pace of over 3
lakh accounts per day
2.
3.7 Figure 3 shows that, despite Jan Dhan’s
record-breaking feats, basic savings account
penetration in most states is still relatively
low – 46 per cent on average and above 75
per cent in only 2 states (Madhya Pradesh
and Chattisgarh). Policymakers thus need to
be cognisant about exclusion errors due to
DBT not reaching unbanked beneficiaries.
Comparing the reach of Jan Dhan with that of
Figure 2: Aadhaar coverage across states
Economic Survey 2015-16
53
Aadhaar suggests that the unbanked are more
likely to constrain the spread of JAM than the
unidentified.
Bank → Beneficiary: the last-mile challenge
of getting money into people’s hands
3.8 Having transferred money to people’s
bank accounts, is the government’s job done?
Perhaps in urban areas, where people live near
banks, even though financial literacy remains
a concern
3 . In rural India, however, there is a
serious “last-mile” problem of getting money
from banks into household’s hands: only 27
per cent of villages have a bank within 5 km
4 .
To help address this problem, the RBI in 2015
licensed 23 new banks – 2 universal banks, 11 Figure 3: Basic Saving Account coverage across states
payment banks and 10 small finance banks.
3.9 While the figures show states’
performance relative to each other, it is
important to benchmark India’s preparedness
against a country where last-mile financial
inclusion is considered good—like Kenya.
The Kenyan BC:population ratio is 1:172.
By contrast, India’s average is 1:6630, less
than 3 per cent of the Kenyan level. Kenya
is more sparsely populated than India, so
perhaps India needs fewer BCs. Yet still the
spatial density of BC’s in India is 17 per cent
the Kenyan level.
3.10 The contrast with India’s mobile
operator penetration is instructive. Figure 5
3 Cole et al (2011)
4 DBT Mission
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
54
Figure 4: One of the missing pieces of JAM – a thriving BC industrySpatial density of BCs – BCs per area
Population density of BCs – People per BC
Economic Survey 2015-16
55
shows that mobile penetration across India is
strong. Only in Bihar (54 per cent) and Assam
(56 per cent) is penetration lower than 60
per cent. Moreover, there are approximately
1.4 million agents or service posts to serve
the approximately 1010 million mobile
customers in India, a ratio of about 1:720.
3.11 India should take advantage of its
deep mobile penetration and agent networks
by making greater use of mobile payments
technology. Mobiles can not only transfer
money quickly and securely, but also improve
the quality and convenience of service delivery. For example, they can inform
beneficiaries that food supplies have arrived
at the ration shop or fertiliser at the local
retail outlet. While some important changes
have occurred this year to improve last-mile
financial connectivity—including the Jan
Dhan Yojana’s initiatives to develop the BC
space and the licensing of several mobile
money operators—the Bank-Beneficiary
connection still appears the weakest link in
the JAM chain.
the
amount and VarIants of Jam
3.12 The ingredients of JAM came together
Figure 5: Mobile coverage across states
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
56
in 2014-15, and Tables 1 and 2 illustrate its
scale and distribution. Over 20 per cent of
India’s population received a cash transfer
from the government in FY14-15. Table 2
shows that JAM was involved in distributing
benefits across a range of government
programs—from education and labour
schemes (scholarships and MGNREGS) to
subsidies and pensions (NSAP). This chapter
studies the two largest JAM schemes in
detail. Box 1 shows that, while MGNREGS
has introduced DBT for paying workers’
wages, JAM remains incomplete. Significant
savings and efficiency gains can be achieved
by transferring funds directly from the state/
central government to the worker rather than
layer by layer (Centre → State → District →
Block → Panchayat), with leakages along the
way. We begin however with the first type of
JAM – DBT in LPG.
Table 1: The Amount of JAM in 2014-15
Total amount disbursed (RCr)44035
No. of beneficiaries (in Cr) 29.6
Beneficiaries seeded with Aadhaar 57%
Funds transfer using Aadhaar Bridge
Payment 26 %
Table 2: The varieties of JAM in FY14-15
Scheme
No. of
Schemes % Share
of total
disbursement
Mahatma Gandhi
National Rural
Employment Guarantee
Scheme (MGNREGS) 1
41
PAHAL (the LPG
subsidy scheme) 1
37
National Social
Assistance Program
(NSAP) 1
14
Scholarship Schemes 297
Other Schemes (Labour,
Women and Banking) 10
1
The first type of JAM – DBT in LPG
3.13 This section studies the Pahal scheme,
which directly transfers LPG subsidies
into customers’ bank accounts. The current
government launched the Pahal scheme
in late 2014 and early 2015, restarting
and modifying a program that the UPA
government had begun and then suspended.
Currently over 151 million beneficiaries
receive LPG subsidies via DBT, and R29,000
crore have been transferred to beneficiaries
to date.
3.14 Household LPG is both untaxed and
enjoys a universal subsidy, even though,
as Chapter 6 shows, 97 per cent of LPG
is consumed by the richest 30 per cent of
households. Before the DBT scheme was
introduced, households could buy LPG
cylinders at subsidised prices (~Rs 430).
Commercial establishments are ineligible
for the subsidy and must pay market prices
plus central and state taxes of about 30 per
cent on average. This violation of the One
Product One Price principle provides strong
incentives for distributors to create ‘ghost’
household accounts and sell subsidised LPG
to businesses in the black market.
3.15 Now, with DBT in place, the
government identifies beneficiaries by
linking households’ LPG customer numbers
with Aadhaar numbers to eliminate ‘ghost’
and duplicate households from beneficiary
rolls
5. Households buy at market prices
(currently ~Rs 670), and have the subsidy
credited into their bank account within 3
days. A permanent advance was made by the
government to reduce household liquidity
constraint issues. The phased introduction of
DBT in LPG allows us to study its impact
by comparing districts that started DBT a
few months earlier to districts that began
DBT slightly later. This research design
helps us control for confounding factors like
seasonality and changing world prices.
5 Aadhaar is not mandatory in the Pahal scheme, but many beneficiaries have chosen to seed their Aadhaar with
their customer numbers.
Economic Survey 2015-16
57
3.16 Figure 6 shows the impact of introducing
and then suspending DBT in LPG. Sales of
subsidised domestic cylinders fell by 24 per
cent when the scheme was introduced and
spiked when the scheme was suspended by
the UPA. Pahal had a similar impact: a 27 per
cent reduction in sale of subsidised cylinders.
Based on prices and subsidy levels in 2014-
15, we estimate that the potential annual
fiscal savings of Pahal will be Rs 12700 crore
in a subsequent FY.
3.17 Before celebrating PAHAL’s success,
it is important to check that reduced sales
of domestic cylinders do not merely reflect
exclusion errors – lower consumption by
genuine beneficiaries who do not have bank
accounts and therefore cannot access the
subsidy under the JAM arrangement. Figure 8
plots the number of LPG cylinders purchased
in the year before DBT introduction against
the percentage in each group who were
receiving the DBT. If exclusion was high
among the poor, groups who consume the
least LPG should have the lowest DBT
compliance rates. But in fact the lowest
compliance rates are for those with the largest
Figure 6: Impact of DBT on subsidised domestic salesprior consumption of LPG cylinders. These
are likely to be ghost households now denied
the subsidy. Figure 8 thus provides some
reassurance that JAM in LPG has succeeded
in reducing leakages rather than excluding
the poor.
3.18 Economic theory would predict the
reduction in black market supply would
increase black market prices. Barnwal (2015)
collected data on black market prices from
both consumers (samosawallahs, hotels and
other commercial retailers) and suppliers
(LPG deliverymen). Table 3 shows that black
market prices spiked by almost 30 per cent in
districts where DBT was introduced.
Table 3: JAMming the LPG black market
Black market price of domestic clylinders
during DBT phase After
suspension
DBTL distircts Rs. 1143
R 861
Non-DBTL districts R 988R 970
Lessons from the LPG experience
3.19 We should also expect that previous
consumers of black market cylinders—such
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
58
Figure 7: DBT causes some substitution to commercial sales
as commercial establishments—are forced by
the introduction of DBT to buy commercial
cylinders. Figure 9 shows evidence that
commercial LPG sales increased when DBT
was introduced and fell back when DBT was
suspended. But the effect is surprisingly
small (6 per cent). What happened? Sales of
non-subsidised domestic cylinders shot up.
While households can buy only 12 subsidised
cylinders a year, they can buy an unlimited
number of unsubsidised cylinders. However
these cylinders are still 30 per cent cheaper
than commercial cylinders due to differential
tax treatment of household and commercial
LPG. The latter is subject to customs and
excise duties of 13 per cent and state taxes of
between 5 per cent (Assam) and 20.5 per cent
(Bihar) over-and-above domestic LPG. This
is a second violation of the One Product One
Price principle and creates another source of
leakage—a shortfall of tax revenue in this
case rather than excess subsidy burden.
Figure 8: Some evidence against genuine exclusion
Economic Survey 2015-16
59
3.20 Another reform that could further
reduce LPG leakages with limited genuine
exclusion is lowering the household cap from
12 to 10. Table 4 shows that even the richest
households—the top 10 per cent—typically
do not consume more than 10 cylinders per
year, so reducing the household cap will be
unlikely to hurt the poor. Moreover, as Figure
9 illustrates, there is a well-known ‘March
problem’ in LPG. Because March is the end
of the fiscal year, distributors have strong
incentives to invoice unconsumed subsidised
cylinders to households and resell them in in
the black market. This explains the observed
spike in March consumption (January and
December consumption are high because
households use LPG for heating during the winter months). Reducing the cap could
significantly reduce this leakage.
Table 4: Household LPG consumption
by decile
Consumption decile RuralUrban
1st 44
2nd 79
3rd 79
4th 710
5th 810
6th 810
7th 810
8th 810
9th 810
10th 810
Source: HPCL administrative data
Box 3.1: Why the government should use JAM for its bread-and-butter functions
Poor households rely on government subsidies to buy certain commodities. In the same way, state and local
governments rely on central transfers to fund key programs, businesses working with government rely on
timely payment to manage cash flow, and government employees rely on government transfers for their
salaries. All receive funds from the same Sarkari financial pipe that delivers subsidies – and which JAM can
improve by reducing delays, leakages, and administrative burden.
This box documents the returns to experimenting with JAM for MGNREGS expenditure in Bihar between
2011 and 2013, and discusses its implications for other schemes and payments.
The figure below shows how the old and new MGNREGS fund flow systems compare, and the Table explains
the two conceptual differences, followed by the effects seen from the Bihar experiment. In the old system,
disbursals were based on forecasted expenditure, and funds sat idle in local government accounts till
expenditures were incurred—though MGNREGS has reformed its system as shown in the figure at the national
level following an August 2015 cabinet note, most other government schemes still follow the old system.
Figure 9: LPG’s March problem
Contd....
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
60
Figure : MGNREGS fund flow systems: old vs. new
Table: Conceptual Differences in Fund Flow Systems
CharacteristicOld system New systemEffect
When are funds
allocated? Before spending occurs, based
on forecasts When spending occurs, in
real-timeReduced float
(26%)
How do funds flow? Level by level:
Centre → State → District →
Block → Panchayat; Directly from fund pool to
spender:
Centre/State → PanchayatReduced payment
delays and
uncertainty
When does
expenditure
documentation
occur? Aggregated and ex-post:
For multiple beneficiaries at
a time, and after funds have
been disbursed Individually and in real-time:
For every individual
beneficiary’s payment and in
order to secure fund releaseReduced leakages
(14%) and funds
disbursed by 38%
The old MGNREGS system (and the current system for most schemes) has 4 major problems:
1. Float: idle funds accrue interest costs for the central government since this is borrowed money. Outside of
MGNREGS, the estimated stock of unspent balances in government accounts is at least Rs 1 lakh crore and
leads to an annual cost of Rs 8500 crore. The new system keeps funds in a central pool and only disburses
expenditure in real-time, reducing float by 26 per cent.
2. Leakages: funds had to pass through multiple layers, meaning more people can demand a cut to secure
the release of funds. Accounting happens ex-post and in aggregate, making monitoring difficult. The new
system reduced leakages by 14 per cent and fund disbursal by 38 per cent even though a household survey
showed no change in the amount of work done in MGNREGA.
3. Misallocation: funds, once disbursed, usually do not return, so forecast errors lead to misallocation of fiscal
resources, with idle funds in some accounts and shortages in others. This leads to scheme shortages for
beneficiaries in some panchayats, even if a neighbouring panchayat has available but unused funds.
4. Resource-intensity: scheme managers spend valuable time haggling with officials at higher administrative
units, who often demand arbitrary documentation to release funds. Similarly, businesses must haggle with
programme managers and face arbitrary requirements to receive payments. The reform has eased the
burdens in doing business with the government, both internally and for vendors.
MGNREGS is one of the government’s largest schemes, and forms 41 per cent of DBT expenditure. Through
fund management reforms, it is overcoming these challenges. Similar gains are possible from adopting these
reforms for all government payments, including other central and state schemes that still use the old model.
Bringing these reforms will require development of IT systems and strong coordination under the auspices
of the Controller General of Accounts. But for the government to reach the world frontier in expenditure
management, it requires a new strategic agency that is precisely the expenditure analog of the Goods and
Services Tax Network—the Expenditure Information Network (EIN)—that must be created to shepherd and
manage this process.
Economic Survey 2015-16
61
Where next to spread JAM?
3.21 DBT in LPG has generally been a big
success, and policymakers in other areas are
understandably keen to emulate its success.
However, when designing DBT schemes
in other areas, caution should be exercised
in drawing lessons from the LPG case.
Several features of LPG made it conducive
to the application of JAM. Table 5 presents
a framework to help policymakers decide
whether—and how—to pursue JAM in
various policy areas. The table is meant to
be illustrative rather than exhaustive. We
organise thinking along 3 categories: first-
mile, middle-mile and last-mile. We now
describe each of these in turn.
First-mile
3.22 First-mile issues deal primarily with
beneficiary eligibility and identification.
• Targeting: targeted subsidies are harder
to JAM than universal programs, as they
require government to have detailed
information about beneficiaries. Subsidies
targeted at the poor (like food and kerosene)
require government to know people’s
wealth, while benefits targeted at farmers
or pregnant mothers require government
to know beneficiaries’ occupation
and pregnancy status respectively. By
contrast, the LPG subsidy is universal; all
households are eligible.
• Beneficiary databases: to identify
beneficiaries, the government needs a
database of eligible individuals. Some
subsidy distributors have beneficiary
lists in digital form, such as the The Oil
Marketing Companies that distribute
LPG subsidies. Customer IDs can then
be seeded with Aadhaar and bank account
information and mobile numbers. Most
states have now digitised their PDS. The
recently released Socioeconomic Census
(SECC) contains information about
household asset-holding and occupation status. This information, if continuously
updated, has the potential to aid targeting
and serve as a baseline database for
administrators in sectors where beneficiary
databases do not yet exist.
• Eligibility: a third issue with identification
is the household-individual connection.
Some benefits are for households
while others are for individuals. For
example, the National Food Security Act
(NFSA) provides for subsidised grain to
households but a cash transfer maternal
entitlement to mothers. Jan Dhan is
monitored at household level, while
Aadhaar is an individual identifier. This
is doubly important because of the way
resources are usually allocated within
households: the (typically male) recipient
of a cash transfer may have different
spending priorities from the (occasionally
female) intended beneficiary.
Middle-mile
3.23 The chief middle-mile issues are the
administrative challenge of coordinating
government actors and the political economy
challenge of sharing rents with supply chain
interest groups.
• Within-government coordination:
ministries and state government
departments share authority in
administering subsidies and transfers.
Some subsidies have more streamlined
administrative arrangements than
others. The LPG subsidy, for instance,
merely requires coordination between
the Union Petroleum Ministry, the 3 Oil
Marketing Companies and the network
of distributors it manages. Coordination
in this setting is significantly easier than
in kerosene, where the Union Petroleum
Ministry must coordinate with the Union
Ministry of Consumer Affairs, Food &
Public Distribution and all the states’
Public Distribution Departments. It is thus
no accident that LPG was the first subsidy
where DBT was introduced!
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
62
• Supply chain interest groups: agents
along a commodity’s supply chain can
obstruct the spread of JAM if their
interests are threatened. The limited
progress in getting Fair Price Shops in
the Public Distribution System (PDS) to
adopt Point of Sale (POS) machines for
biometric authentication is suggestive
of such resistance. Profits are required
for FPS, fertiliser retail outlets and other
distributors to remain viable, and ought
to be seen as a feature, not a bug, in
subsidy design. Rents must be shared for
reform to proceed, and thus distributors
need incentives before they invest in
JAM infrastructure. The hold-up power
of groups within the subsidy system is
an example of the Indian’s economy exit
problem (Chapter 2).
Last-mile
3.24 Last-mile issues relate to the risks of
excluding genuine beneficiaries, especially
the poor. These depend on two factors:
• Beneficiary financial inclusion:
exclusion errors can be substantial if few
beneficiaries have bank accounts and
can easily access them. Bank account
penetration is growing, thanks to Jan Dhan,
but in rural areas physical connectivity to
the banking system remains limited, and
BCs and mobile money providers have
not yet solved this last-mile problem. A
subsidy’s share of rural consumers is thus
a rough proxy of the level of beneficiary
financial inclusion.
• Beneficiary vulnerability: exclusion
error risks increase when the beneficiary
population is poorer. The poorest 3 deciles
of Indian households consume only 3 per
cent of subsidised LPG consumption, but
49 per cent of subsidised kerosene.
So, where and how to JAM?
3.25 We argue that policymakers should
decide where next to JAM based on two considerations:
•
Size of leakages: as shown in Box 1 and
the previous section, JAM significantly
reduced leakages in LPG and MGNREGS
with limited exclusion of the poor. The
returns from pursuing JAM in other areas
depends on the size of leakages in those
sectors. Subsidies with higher leakages
have larger returns from introducing JAM.
• Central government control: when
introducing JAM, policymakers will
confront administrative challenges in
coordinating central and state government
departments, and political challenges in
bringing the supply chain interest groups
like Fair Price Shops on board with DBT.
3.26 Based on these considerations, the
policy areas that appear most conducive to
JAM are those where the central government
has significant control and where leakages—
and hence fiscal savings due to JAM—are
high. Table 5 shows that this combination is
met for fertiliser and within-government fund
transfers.
3.27 We consider two JAM options: DBT
and BAPU—Biometrically Authenticated
Physical Uptake. With DBT, subsidies are
transferred to beneficiaries in cash. With
BAPU, beneficiaries certify their identity
using Aadhaar and then physically take the
subsidised goods like today. In the next
section we evaluate states’ preparedness to
implement these two JAM options
JAM Preparedness Index
3.28 We construct an index to measure
states’ preparedness to implement (i) DBT in
urban areas, (ii) DBT in rural areas, and (iii)
BAPU. Table 6 shows the indicators used to
construct the various indices:
3.30 Because each condition is necessary
and none on its own is sufficient, our index
is not the average but the minimum of the
respective indicators. Using the minimum is
a way of highlighting the binding constraints
along the JAM chain
6. 6 The idea of binding constraints appeared in a well-known paper called “The O-ring theory” by Kremer (1993).
Economic Survey 2015-16
63
Table 5: The spread of JAM across the Indian economy
LPGKerosene FoodFertiliser Within-govt
JAM
First-mile Eligibility
HouseholdHousehold HouseholdIndividual Scheme
Targeting UniversalTargeted
(BPL) Targeted
(BPL)Targeted
(farmers) All central
government
scheme
expenditure
Beneficiary
database Digitised
Most
digitised Most
digitisedNone
Public
Finance
Management
System
Middle-mile Within-
government
coordination Central
Petroleum
Ministry
with
OMCsCentral
Petroleum
& Food
Ministries
with all State
PDS Central Food
Ministry with
all State PDS
Central
Fertiliser
Ministry
with fertiliser
manufacturers Expenditure
Department
with Central
Ministries
Supply chain
interest groups LPG
distributorsFair Price
Shops Fair Price
ShopsFertiliser
retailers N/A
Last-mile Beneficiary
vulnerability 3%
49% 51%62% N/A
Beneficiary
financial
inclusion 33%
83% 78%100% N/A
Where to
JAM? Leakages
24%46% Wheat - 54%,
Rice - 15%40%
14%
Central
government
control High
Low LowHigh Very High
What kind
of JAM? Recommended
policy option
JAM
BAPU BAPUBAPU/JAM JAM
Table 6: Indicators in the JAM preparedness index
Urban DBT Rural DBTBAPU
Can government identify
beneficiaries? Aadhaar penetration
Aadhaar penetrationAadhaar
penetration
Authenticating
transactions POS machines
Paying beneficiaries Basic bank account penetration Basic bank account
penetration
Beneficiaries accessing
money BC density
BC density
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
64
Figure 10: JAM preparedness index – Urban
3.31 We begin with the Urban DBT index,
shown in Figure 10. There is significant
variation across states. Some, like Madhya
Pradesh and Chattisgarh, show preparedness
scores of about 70 per cent. Others, like Bihar
and Maharashtra, have scores of only about
25 per cent. As described earlier in the chapter
the binding constraint here is basic bank
account penetration—paying beneficiaries is
the issue, not identifying them.
3.32 The Rural DBT preparedness index
adds an additional indicator: BC density as
a ratio of the Kenyan level (Figure 11). We use Kenya as a benchmark – intuitively as the
100 per cent level – because it is a country
where banking agent networks appear to be
functioning relatively well in rural areas.
The DBT rural preparedness scores are
significantly worse than the urban scores,
with an average of 3 per cent and a maximum
of 5 per cent (Haryana). Comparing the rural
and urban indexes—i.e. Figures 10 and 11—
it is clear that last-mile financial inclusion is
the main constraint to making JAM happen in
much of rural India. Jan Dhan’s vision must
truly succeed before much of India can JAM.
Economic Survey 2015-16
65
Figure 11: JAM preparedness index - Rural
3.33 What can be done to reduce leakages in
the meantime, while banking correspondent
networks develop and mobile banking
spreads? One possibility would be what we
call BAPU—Biometrically Authenticated
Physical Uptake. Beneficiaries verify their
identities through scanning their thumbprint
on a POS machine while buying the
subsidised product—say kerosene at the PDS
shop. This is being successfully attempt by
Krishna district in Andhra Pradesh, with
significant leakage reductions. Despite financial inclusion scores being low, if Fair
Price Shops are equipped with POS machines,
beneficiaries can simply authenticate their
identities while taking their rations as under
the current system. BAPU preparedness is
much better than for Rural DBT preparedness.
The average state preparedness is 12 per cent
(Figure 12), but there are some states – like
Andhra Pradesh (96 per cent), Chattisgarh
(42 per cent) and Madhya Pradesh (27 per
cent) – that with some policy push could be
well-prepared for BAPU in the near future.
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
66
Figure 12: BAPU Preparedness Index
conclusIon
3.36 We conclude with policy
recommendations on LPG and the broader
spread of JAM.
LPG
3.37 The Pahal scheme has been a big
success. The use of Aadhaar has made
black marketing harder, and LPG leakages
have reduced by about 24 per cent with
limited exclusion of genuine beneficiaries.
However, diversion of LPG from domestic to commercial sources continues, because of
the differential tax treatment of “commercial”
and “domestic” LPG. In other words, the
One Product One Price principle is still being
violated. Diversion could be further reduced
by equalising taxes across end-uses. This
will not necessarily be inequitable because
as Chapter 6 shows, LPG subsidies almost
entirely benefit the well-off.
Broader spread of JAM
3.38
Considerable work needs to be done
to fully implement the game-changing JAM
Economic Survey 2015-16
67
agenda. In those areas where the centre
has less control, it should incentivise the
states to invest in first-mile capacity (by
improving beneficiary databases), deal with
middle-middle challenges (by designing
incentives for supply chain interest groups
to support DBT) and improve last-mile
financial connectivity (by developing the
BC and mobile money space). To this end,
states should be incentivised by sharing fiscal
savings from DBT.
3.39 Meanwhile, the centre should prioritise
areas where it has the highest control over the
first- and middle-mile factors and leakages
are high. Fertiliser and within-government
transfers stand out as good candidates. The
example of MGNREGS highlights that
delivering within-government transfers via
JAM can help other centrally sponsored
schemes reduce idle funds, lower corruption
and improve the ease of doing business with
government. 3.40
Despite huge improvements in
financial inclusion due to Jan Dhan, the JAM
preparedness indicators suggest that there is
still some way to go before bank-beneficiary
linkages are strong enough to pursue DBT
without committing exclusion errors. In
that sense, the JAM agenda is currently
jammed by the last-mile challenge of getting
money from banks into beneficiaries’ hands,
especially in rural India. The centre can invest
in last-mile financial inclusion via further
improving BC networks and promoting the
spread of mobile money. The recent licensing
of banks will help. Regulations governing
the remuneration of BCs may need to be
reviewed to ensure that commission rates are
sufficient to encourage BCs to remain active.
3.41 In the meantime models like BAPU
offer the prospect of lower leakages without
the risk of exclusion errors, and therefore
merit serious consideration.
Spreading JAM across Indias economy
Agriculture: More from Less
04
IntroductIon
4.1 Mahatma Gandhi believed that India
lives in villages and agriculture is the soul of
Indian economy. These words still ring true
today. Agriculture brings home the bread to
nearly half of all households and supplies it to
the remainder. And, while non-farm activities
are becoming increasingly important, there is
still a core truth in Theodore Schultz’ Nobel
Prize lecture: “Most of the world's poor
people earn their living from agriculture, so
if we knew the economics of agriculture, we
would know much of the economics of being
poor.”
4.2 Indian agriculture has come a long
way since independence, with chronic food
scarcity giving way to grain self-sufficiency
despite a two-and-a-half fold increase in population. In 1966-67, just before India’s
Green and White Revolutions, Indian wheat
and milk production were just about one-
third of US output. By 2013-14, Indian
wheat output was 60 per cent higher than
America’s, while Indian milk output was 50
per cent higher. These tremendous increases
in aggregate output do, however, mask some
disquieting trends.
4.3
At the heart of the problem is one of
lack of exit (the theme of Chapter 2). Indian
agriculture, is in a way, a victim of its own
success, which over time is posing to be a
major threat. Indian agriculture has become
cereal-centric and as a result, regionally-
biased and input-intensive, consuming
generous amounts of land, water, and fertiliser.
Encouraging other crops, notably pulses (via
Indian agriculture, is in a way, a victim of its own past success—especially the
green revolution. It has become cereal-centric and as a result, regionally-biased
and input-intensive (land, water, and fertiliser). Rapid industrialization and
climate change are raising the scarcity value of land and water, respectively.
Evolving dietary patterns are favoring greater protein consumption. To adapt
to these changes, agriculture requires a new paradigm with the following
components: increasing productivity by getting “more from less” especially
in relation to water via micro irrigation; prioritizing the cultivation of less
water-intensive crops, especially pulses and oil-seeds, supported by a favorable
Minimum Support Price (MSP) regime that incorporates the full social benefits
of producing such crops and backed by a strengthened procurement system; and
re-invigorating agricultural research and extension in these crops. Finally, we
provide evidence of deep segmentation in Indian agricultural markets which,
if remedied, would create one Indian agricultural market and boost farmers’
incomes.
CHAPTER
69
a Rainbow Revolution to follow the Green
and White Revolutions) will be necessary to
match supply with evolving dietary patterns
that favor greater proteins consumption. At
the same time, rapid industrialization and
climate change will require economizing on
land and water, respectively—getting “more
from less” of these inputs.
4.4 Figure 1 depicts the land challenge, and
shows the sharp decline in cultivable land per
person in India—much sharper than in other
countries. Over the next twenty years, India’s
fast population growth will make the cross-
country comparison even less favorable
for India. Figure 2 highlights the water
challenge. It shows that India has much lower
levels of water per capita than Brazil, one of
the world’s leading agricultural countries.
This constraint is exacerbated because, while
Brazil and China use approximately 60 per
cent of their renewable fresh water resources
for agriculture, India uses a little over 90 per
cent.
4.5 Agriculture is deserving of several
treatises (Niti Aayog, 2015). Given the
constraints of space, this chapter focuses
on the core issues of engineering a switch
toward pulses and the need to economize
on the use of water. We first present data on
Indian productivity compared with frontier
productivity in cereals and pulses. The next
section elaborates on the “more from less”
imperative with a focus on economizing
water via micro irrigation. (The scope for
economizing on fertiliser is discussed in
Chapter 9). Thereafter, we discuss how the
policy on Minimum Support Prices (MSP)
should be geared towards increasing pulses
production, followed by a section highlighting
the complementary investments required in
agricultural research and extension . The final
section, building on last year’s Economic
Survey, presents some new findings on the
extent of segmentation of Indian agricultural
markets. The findings emphasize the need
for expediting action to create one Indian common market in agriculture, which would
increase the returns to farmers substantially.
4.6 Certain very important issues, ranging
from crop insurance (where the government
has been taking important steps to protect
farmers against natural and market shocks)
to land leasing, to rural infrastructure, to the
livestock sector, are not addressed in this
chapter.
ProductIvIty
The macro picture
4.7 The central challenge of Indian agriculture
is low productivity, evident in modest
average yields, especially in pulses. First,
consider the main food grains – wheat and
rice. These two cereals are grown on the most
fertile and irrigated areas in the country. And
Agriculture: More from Less
70
1 One caveat while comparing paddy yields is that varieties are not exactly homogenous. Also the differences
between varieties are large.
they use a large part of the resources that the
government channels to agriculture, whether
water, fertiliser, power, credit or procurement
under the MSP program. Even then, average
yields of wheat and rice in India are much
below that of China’s – 46 per cent below in
the case of rice and 39 per cent in the case of
wheat.
4.8 In wheat (Figure 3), India’s average
yield in 2013 of 3075 kg/ha is lower than the
world average of 3257 kg/ha. Although both
Punjab and Haryana have much higher yields
of 4500 kg/ha, most other Indian states have
yields lower than that of Bangladesh.
4.9 The picture is starker in paddy
production (Figure 4)
1 where all Indian states
have yields below that of China and most
states have yields below that of Bangladesh.
India’s best state, Punjab, has paddy yield
close to 6000 kg/ha whereas China’s yield is
6709 kg/ha.
4.10 India happens to be the major producer
and consumer of pulses, which is one of the
major sources of protein for the population.
India has low yields comparable to most
countries. On an average, countries like
Brazil, Nigeria, and Myanmar have higher
yields (Figure 5). Some states do much better
than the all-India average, but even the key
pulse producing state of Madhya Pradesh has
yields (938 kg/ha) barely three-fifths that of
China’s (1550 kg/ha). These comparisons are
based on the basket of pulses grown in each
country. If we compare yields of just tur (or
pigeon peas) across countries, the qualitative
picture is no different (Figure 6). Given that
India is the major producer and consumer of
pulses, imports cannot be the main source for
meeting domestic demand. Therefore, policy
must incentivise movement of resources
towards production of pulses.
Economic Survey 2015-16
71
4.11 All four figures carry one important
message: India could make rapid gains in
productivity through convergence within
India. For example, in pulses, if all states were
to attain even Bihar’s level of productivity,
pulses production would increase by an
estimated 41 per cent
2 on aggregate.
Where are croPs GroWn? a double
b
loW for Pulses
2 We arrive at this rough estimate by applying Bihar’s pulses productivity level from Figure 5, to the aggregate area
under pulses production in a state and comparing it to its current quantity produced. The latter two data points
were obtained from data.gov.in (https://www.data.gov.in/catalog/district-wise-season-wise-crop-production-
statistics).
4.12 To better understand the productivity
challenge, an analysis of the allocation of
irrigated land by crop is instructive. Data from
the “Situation of Agricultural Households
Survey, 2013” by the NSSO allows an
estimation of the percentage of crops grown
on un-irrigated land across different states.
The data is summarized in Figures 7-10.
.
Agriculture: More from Less
72
.
Economic Survey 2015-16
73
4.13 It is immediately apparent that the
production pattern for pulses is very different
from other crops. Not only is most of the land
dedicated to growing pulses in each state un-
irrigated, but the national output of pulses
comes predominantly from un-irrigated land.
In contrast, a large share of output in wheat,
rice and sugarcane – in Punjab, Haryana and
UP – is from irrigated land. In water scarce
Maharashtra, all sugarcane is grown on
irrigated land. Meeting the high and growing
demand for pulses in the country will
require large increases in pulses production
on irrigated land, but this will not occur if
agriculture policies continue to focus largely
on cereals and sugarcane.
What does thIs mean for farm
I
ncomes?
4.14 The negative consequences of low
agriculture yields extend from precarious
incomes of farmers to large tracts of land
locked in low value agriculture, despite
growing demands for high value products
such as fruits, vegetables, livestock products because of consumption diversification with
rising incomes and urbanization. According
to NSS data, the average annual income of
the median
3 farmer net of production costs
from cultivation is less than R20,000 in 17
states (Figure 11).
4 This includes produce that
farmers did not sell (presumably used for self-
consumption) valued at local market prices.
Given high wedges between retail and farm
gate price, this might underestimate income
but it is still low. Moreover, the variance in
agriculture income between the more and
less productive states is also very stark.
crItIcal InPut: Water
4.15 Although water is one of India’s most
scarce natural resources, India uses 2 to
4 times more water to produce a unit of
major food crop than does China and Brazil
(Hoekstra and Chapagain [2008]). Hence,
it is imperative that the country focus on
improving the efficiency of water use in
agriculture.
4.16 Since independence India has invested
numerous resources on irrigation, both
3 Median refers to the median farmer of each state by net income. We have subsequently backed out the
corresponding land holding size of farmers from the NSS data.
4 Ideally this net income estimates should be conditional on the monsoon. However, data for such analysis was
unavailable.
Agriculture: More from Less
74
5 “NASA Satellites Unlock Secret to Northern India's Vanishing Water”. December 2009. http://www.nasa.gov/
topics/earth/features/india_water.html
6 Gale, Fred; Hansen, James; and, Jewison, Michael. China’s Growing Demand for Agricultural Imports. February
2015. United States Department of Agriculture (http://www.ers.usda.gov/media/1784488/eib136.pdf ) and
Agriculture and trade policy: Background note. http://tinyurl.com/z3gecmx
7 India’s Agricultural Exports Climb to Record High. August 2014. United States Department of Agriculture. http://
tinyurl.com/glng3nf
8 Fertigation is the process of introducing fertiliser directly into the crop’s irrigation system.
public (canal irrigation) and private (tube
wells). In both cases the water has been
deployed via “flood” irrigation, which
is an extremely inefficient use of water.
Irrigation investments must shift to adopting
technologies like sprinkler and drip irrigation
and rainwater harvesting (leveraging labour
available under the MGNREGS where
possible). In order to facilitate this shift,
the new irrigation technologies need to be
accorded “infrastructure lending” status
(currently accorded to canal irrigation) and
both the centre and states need to increase
public spending for micro irrigation. The
consolidation of ongoing irrigation schemes –
the Accelerated Irrigation Benefit Programme
(AIBP), Integrated Watershed Management
Programme (IWMP) and On Farm Water
Management (OFWM) – into the Prime
Minister’s Krishi Sinchayi Yojana (PMKSY)
offers the possibility of convergence of
investments in irrigation, from water source
to distribution and end-use.
4.17 It has long been recognized that a key
factor undermining the efficient use of water
is subsidies on power for agriculture that,
apart from its benefits towards farmers,
incentivises wasteful use of water and hasten
the decline of water tables. According to an
analysis by National Aeronautics and Space
Administration (NASA)
5 , India’s water
tables are declining at a rate of 0.3 meters per
year. Between 2002 and 2008, the country
consumed more than 109 cubic kilometers of
groundwater, double the capacity of India's
largest surface water reservoir, the Upper
Wainganga.
4.18 It is also noteworthy that India, a water- scarce country, has been “exporting water”
as a result of distorted incentives. Goswami
and Nishad (2015) estimate water content
embedded in crops at the time of trade. This
is different from water used in production,
which is much higher. Water “embedded”
in crops is the water content of each crop
and once the crop is exported, it cannot be
recovered. In 2010, India exported about 25
cu km of water embedded in its agricultural
exports. This is equivalent to the demand of
nearly 13 million people.
4.19 India was a “net importer” of water until
around 1980s. With increases in food grain
exports, India has now become a net exporter
of water – about 1 per cent of total available
water every year. The ratio of export to
import of such virtual water is about 4 for
India and 0.1 for China. Thus China remains
a net importer of water. This is also evident
in China and India’s trade patterns. China
imports water-intensive soybeans, cotton,
meat and cereal grains
6, while exporting
vegetables, fruits and processed food. India,
on the other hand, exports water-intensive
rice, cotton, sugar and soybean.
7
mIcro IrrIGatIon
4.20 A promising way forward, to increase
productivity while conserving water (more
for less), is to adopt micro irrigation methods.
In drip irrigation for example, perforated
pipes are placed either above or slightly
below ground and drip water on the roots
and stems of plants, directing water more
precisely to crops that need it. An efficient
drip irrigation system reduces consumption
of fertiliser (through fertigation
8) and water
Economic Survey 2015-16
75
lost to evaporation, and higher yields than
traditional flood irrigation.
4.21 The key bottlenecks in the adoption
of this technology are the high initial
cost of purchase and the skill required for
maintenance. However, the increase in yields
and reduction in costs of power and fertiliser
use can help farmers recover the fixed cost
quickly. Provisions for credit to farmers
can incentivise greater adoption of this
technology.
9
4.22 Results from an impact evaluation of
National Mission on Micro Irrigation (of
the Ministry of Agriculture, Government of
India) conducted in 64 districts of 13 states
– Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Chhattisgarh,
Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Maharashtra,
Odisha, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Sikkim, Uttar
Pradesh and Uttarakhand – are revealing on
the benefits of drip irrigation.
4.23 There were substantial reductions in
irrigation costs and savings on electricity and
fertilisers (Figure 12). This is because water is
efficiently supplied and hence pumps are used
for a limited time. Moreover, water soluble
fertilisers are supplied directly to the roots
9 However, ensuring that credit effectively reaches target groups in agriculture is not a small challenge (see Box 5.2
in Economic Survey 2014-15).
of the plant and hence there is less wastage.
Yields of crops also went up – up to 45 per
cent in wheat, 20 per cent in gram and 40 per
cent in soybean. The resulting improvement
in net farm incomes is substantial. Until now
micro-irrigation techniques, owing to high
fixed costs of adoption, have mostly been
used for high value crops. However, recent
research has shown its feasibility even in
wheat and rice.
PolIcIes
Minimum Support Price and Procurement
Policy
4.24 When planting crops, farmers face
several uncertainties in terms of their realized
prices in the several months following their
harvest. In principle, a farmer could buy an
option contract to reduce this price uncertainty
and make corresponding cropping decisions,
but in reality this option is unavailable for all
but a miniscule fraction of India’s farmers.
4.25 Instead, future prices are guaranteed by
the government through the MSP. But while
the government announces MSP for 23 crops,
effective MSP-linked procurement occurs
Agriculture: More from Less
76
mainly for wheat, rice and cotton. While
there is no government procurement per se
in sugarcane, a crop with assured irrigation,
mills are legally obligated to buy cane from
farmers at prices fixed by government, an
effective MSP-like engangement. But even
for these crops MSP is restricted to a subset
of farmers in a few states. This can be clearly
observed in large gaps in the percentage of
farmers who are even aware of the MSP
policy (Figure 13).
4.26 In Punjab and Haryana, almost all
paddy and wheat farmers are aware of the
MSP policy. However, very few farmers who
grow pulses are aware of an MSP for pulses.
Even for paddy and wheat where active
procurement occurs, there is a substantial
variation across states – with only half or less
paddy and wheat farmers reporting awareness
of MSP, especially in states such as, Gujarat,
Maharashtra, Rajasthan, Andhra Pradesh and Jharkhand. This points to the possibility that
procurement in these states may be happening
in some districts and not in others.
4.27 Thus, while in principle MSP exists
for most farmers for most crops, its realistic
impact is quite limited for most farmers in
the country. Public procurement at MSP has
disproportionately focused on wheat, rice and
sugarcane and perhaps even at the expense of
other crops such as pulses and oilseeds. This
has resulted in buffer stocks of paddy and
wheat to be above the required norms, but
also caused frequent price spikes in pulses
and edible oils, despite substantial imports of
these commodities.
4.28 The absence of MSP procurement for
most crops in most states implies either
that farmers are selling their products to
private intermediaries above the MSP or the
converse, i.e., farmers have little option but
to sell their produce at prices below the MSP,
Economic Survey 2015-16
77
resulting in a regional bias in farm incomes.
There is a general sense that the latter is a
more prevalent phenomenon, highlighting
the need for reorienting agriculture price
policies, such that MSPs are matched by
public procurement efforts towards crops that
better reflect the country’s natural resource
scarcities.
4.29 One way of rationalizing MSP policy
is to make these price signals reflect social
rather than just private returns of production.
Table 1 provides an illustrative example for
quantifying these private and social returns to
cultivating different crops.
4.30 Table 1 estimates the returns to growing
wheat, sugarcane or paddy, taking account of
the negative externalities from using chemical
fertiliser (soil depletion and health), water
(falling water tables), and from burning crops
(adverse health consequences). Conversely,
the social returns to pulse production is
higher than the private returns, because it not
only uses less water and fertiliser but fixes
atmospheric nitrogen naturally and helps
keep the soil porous and well aerated because
of its deep and extensive root systems. These
positive social benefits should be incorporated
into MSP estimates.
4.31 Farmers could also be assured a
Table 1: Crop-wise return in Punjab during TE 2010-11
Crop NameSeasonReturn at
market
prices (Rs/ ha) Return based
on social
contribution (Rs/ ha)Difference in
social and private returns (Rs/ha)* Difference in
social and private returns (% of
market prices)*
Chick-pea Rabi2633 52952,662 101%
Lentil Rabi11349 13584 2,235 20%
Blackgram Kharif1564 30571,493 95%
Wheat Rabi36244 27017(9227) (25%)
Paddy-non Basmati Kharif46198 32412(13786) (30%)
Paddy-Basmati Kharif53377 40534(12843) (24%)
Sugarcane(Planted) Kharif98384 82163(16221) (16%)
Sugarcane(Ratoon) Kharif118676 103779(14898) (13%)
Source: Niti Aayog. The estimates were undertaken as part of the Regional Crop planning for improving resource use
efficiency and sustainability at ICAR-NIAP, New Delhi.
* negative(positive) value in the column indicates adverse (favourabl\
e) social externalities.
floor price for their crops through a “Price
Deficiency Payment” (Niti Aayog [2015]).
Under this system if the price in an Agriculture
Produce Market Committee (APMC) mandi
fell below the MSP then the farmer would be
entitled to a maximum of, say, 50 per cent
of the difference between the MSP and the
market price. This subsidy could be paid to the
farmer via Direct Benefits Transfer (DBT).
Such a system would keep the quantum of the
subsidy bill in check and also be consistent
with India’s obligations to the WTO.
aGrIcultural research and
e
ducatIon
4.32 Addressing India’s multiple challenges
in agriculture will require significant
upgradation of country’s national agriculture
research and extension systems.
4.33 India’s National Agricultural Research
System (NARS) (comprising the Indian
Council of Agricultural Research (ICAR),
other central research institutes, and national
research centres set up by ICAR), together
with agriculture research universities played
a key role in the Green revolution. In more
recent years, however, agriculture research
has been plagued by severe under investment
and neglect.
Agriculture: More from Less
78
4.34 The system has been sapped by three
weaknesses. One, in states where agriculture
is relatively more important (as measured
by their share of agriculture in state GDP),
agriculture education is especially weak if
measured by the number of students enrolled
in agricultural universities (Figure 14). This
is especially true in states in the Northern
(except Punjab and Haryana) and Eastern
regions. The agriculture universities have
been plagued by: (i) resource crunch, (ii)
difficulty in attracting talented faculty, (iii)
limited linkages and collaborations with
international counterparts, (iv) weakening
of the lab-to-land connect; and, (v) lack of
innovation (Tamboli and Nene [2013] and
Niti Aayog [2015]).
4.35 The weaknesses of state agriculture
universities (SAU) imply that extension
systems critical for the diffusion of new
agricultural innovations and practices, or even
dissemination of information about public
programs such as MSP, are unable to achieve
their intended objectives. Urgent intervention
in this respect is therefore currently required
of the states.
4.36 Second, investment in public agricultural
research in India needs to be augmented.
Given the large externalities, the centre
needs to play a more important role. India’s
current spending on agriculture research is
considerably below that of China and as a
share of agriculture GDP even less than that
of Bangladesh and Indonesia (Figure 15).
4.37 Third, resource augmentation can go
only so far unless accompanied by changes
in incentives. There is a strong need to take
steps to enhance research productivity among
the scientists in public agriculture research
institutes by instituting performance indicators
“as the majority (63.5 per cent) of scientists
[had] low to very low level of productivity.”
(Paul et. al. [2015]). For example, the rapid rate of innovation required in pulses can be
achieved by securing participation from the
private sector, which hitherto, has remained
largely limited due to the small scale of
pulse production in the country. This can
potentially be of the form of a pull system
of research, similar to Kremer’s HIV/AIDS
vaccine idea, albeit with a smaller quantum
of reward. In such a system, the winner is
offered a proportionately large enough award
for innovating desirable agricultural traits,
but the intellectual property rights of the
innovation are transferred to the government.
The policy should however, seek to level the
playing field for private, public and citizen
sector participation.
4.38 Similarly, private sector innovation
and high yielding variety in seeds can result
in productivity gains. Currently, the seed
replacement rate for pulses are in the range of
19 per cent to 34 per cent,
10 highlighting the
need for greater private sector engagement in
order to spur innovation and high yields.
4.39 India should also fully leverage new low-
cost technologies that have wider benefits for
agriculture. Cellphones have been creatively
used by countries like Ghana, Kenya, Nigeria
and Thailand to provide information on
prices and cultivation to farmers which has
led to massive increases in farm incomes.
Since the costs of drones have fallen sharply,
they can be used by SAUs to provide crucial
information on crop health, irrigation
problems, soil variation and even pest and
fungal infestations that are not apparent at
eye level to farmers. Small efforts can go a
long way in mitigating farm losses and risks
and maximizing income.
4.40 A host of studies has demonstrated
significant net benefits of GM crops (Kathage
and Qaim [2012]) with leading countries such
as Brazil and now China opening up to new
GM technologies and aggressively building
10 State wise seed replacement rates are from Seednet, http://seednet.gov.in/PDFFILES/SRR-13.pdf ; Data cited is for 2011-12, the latest available estimates.
Economic Survey 2015-16
79
their own research capacity. Nonetheless
there are good reasons for some of the public
apprehensions on GMOs. Therefore, the
regulatory process in India needs to evolve so
as to address the concerns in a way that does
not come in the way adapting high yielding
technologies and rapidly moving towards the
world's agro-technological frontier.
11 Source: Lok Sabha unstarred question number 5645, dated 28.04.2015, NSS \
SAS 2013 and Agriculture Statistics
at a Glance 2014.
12 Source: Stads, G.J. 2015. "A snapshot of agricultural research investment and capacity in Asia." ASTI Resource
Paper for the Asia Pacific Association of Agricultural Research Institutions’ High Level Policy Dialogue,
Bangkok. December 2015. Washington, DC: International Food Policy Research Institute.
market faIlure for aGrIcultural
o
utPut
Market Segmentation
4.41 Market segmentation reduces overall
welfare because it prevents gains through
competition, efficient resource allocation,
specialization in subsectors and fewer
Agriculture: More from Less
80
13 The prices are constructed as state wise averages of prices received by farmers in that state for India. The US prices were obtained from the United States Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service
http://www.nass.usda.gov/
14 We recognize that these estimates should ideally be compared to similar emerging market economies today. We
used the US as a benchmark because historical data going back to 1960 was more easily available. Moreover, a
comparison between India today and the US in 1960 controls, to some exte\
nt, for the stage of development.
15 India, 2013 farmgate prices were procured from NSS SAS 2013. The data for US-1960 and US-2013 is obtained
from United States Department of Agriculture, National Agricultural Statistics Service http://www.nass.usda.
gov/
intermediaries. Massive railroad expansion in
the late 19th Century changed the landscape
of agriculture markets in the United States.
The resulting gains due to the increase in
market integration is estimated to be around
60 per cent in terms of land value (Donaldson
and Hornbeck [2015]) and 90 per cent in
terms of output (Costinot and Donaldson
[2011]).
4.42 The causes of market segmentation
are many – differences in remoteness and
connectivity (rural roads), local market
power of intermediaries, degree of private
sector competition, propensity of regional
exposure to shocks, local storage capacity,
mandi infrastructure and farmers access to
them, storage life of the crop and crop specific
processing cost.
4.43 Market segmentation results in large differences in producer and consumer prices.
Although these differences are location-
specific, they result in higher costs for
both farmers and consumers alike. This is
immediately apparent if one compares India
to the US. In Figure 16, price
13 dispersion for
prices received by farmers is measured as
the ratio between the highest (P95) and the
lowest (P5) price of the crop in a country, i.e.
if this ratio were to be equal to one, it would
imply that there is no price dispersion, and
that there is one common market.
14
4.44 India’s price dispersion across
commodities (the left-most graph) is a stark
contrast to those of the U.S. even in the
1960s. For example, in 2012 in the United
States the maximum price dispersion is for
peanuts, which hardly exceeds 1.75, much
higher than the minimum observed for any
Source: NSS Situation Assessment Survey of Agriculture Households Round 70, United States National Agricultural
Statistics Service
Economic Survey 2015-16
81
agriculture commodity in India (i.e., tur). In
effect, price dispersion in India is about 100
per cent-45 per cent greater than in the US
today or the US in 1960.
4.45 As noted earlier, segmentation also
creates a “wedge” at various points in the
supply chain from the farm-gate to the final
consumer in India. Quantifying these price
wedges across agents spread over the supply
chain is complex given data constraints, but
we have attempted some rough estimates.
PrIce WedGes
4.46 The graphs below quantify the wedges between farm-gate and wholesale prices
and then between retail and wholesale
prices for certain crops. Several layers of
intermediary networks exist between farmers
and wholesale markets and also between
wholesale and retail markets, data for which
is unavailable. Consequently, this analysis
is unable to isolate the contribution of each
of these intermediaries and other sources of
price wedges such as transportation costs,
storage capacity and other factors listed
above (see Appendix 6, Technical Appendix,
Chapter-4 for a full set of assumptions). With
these caveats, the estimates are provided in
Figures 17 and 18.
4.47
Figure 17, which examines farm gate-
wholesale price wedges,
16 indicates that
the biggest price wedges are for potatoes,
onions and groundnuts. The wedges are
lower for rice, wheat (two commodities that are produced by a large majority of farmers
and where MSP declaration is followed by
government procurement) and interestingly
for maize. The wedges for pulses (tur and
moong) are not as high as potatoes, onions and
16
The data for farm gate price is NSS SAS 2013. The data for wholesale prices is from http://www.agmarknet.in
for the same year and season as NSS SAS 2013.
Source: NSS SAS Round 70, 2013; Agmarknet
Agriculture: More from Less
82
groundnuts. It appears that the perishability
of a product is an important factor driving the
wedges.
17
4.48 The estimates are qualitatively similar
when we look at wedges between the retail
and wholesale markets (Figure 18). The
analysis (for 2014) finds higher markups in
perishables such as onions than in cereals and
pulses. Higher markups in rice might reflect
the processing cost of paddy. But in addition
to the price wedges across commodities
there is also substantial variation in wedges
for the same commodities across states. If
processing and other costs are similar across
17 The calculation of wedges does control for crop variety. Given limited information about quality and varieties in
the retail and farm-gate price data, we have tried to allay these concerns as best as we could by comparing median
prices over similar distances. As a robustness check, in analysis not reported here, we also tried comparing the
80th percentile of wholesale to the 40th percentile of retail prices and\
the results did not change much.
18 Statistical tests for market integration, derived from the law of one price, look at whether prices o\
f similar goods
in different markets co-move with each other. They can also test for whether the co-movements fail in either the
short- or the long-run or both. However, a broader understanding of market segmentation is also whether local
shocks do not spread geographically. Hence, the wedges (which measure prices in changes and not in levels)
should not be location specific if markets are perfectly integrated. Our analysis should be viewed in that spirit.
states then higher markups for certain states
across commodities is a reflection of state
specific effects – which could range from
rural infrastructure, storage capacities to
the rural political economy. For example,
Karnataka, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra
and Karnataka appear to have higher markups
across commodities.
4.49 Chapter 8 of last year’s Economic
Survey addressed the need for a national
market for agricultural commodities
India. The analysis above shows the large
magnitude of price wedges both across
commodities as well as across states
18. It
Figure 18: Wedges between Retail and Wholesale Prices
Source: Agmarknet APMC Mandi Prices;
Retail Prices from Ministry of Agriculture,
Government of India.
Economic Survey 2015-16
83
illustrates an important point: greater market
integration is essential for farmers to get
higher farm gate prices. While the GST bill is
a step in the right direction, a lot more needs
to be done by the states, including, creating
better physical infrastructure, improved price dissemination campaigns, and removing laws
that force farmers to sell to local monopolies,
etc. Nearly seventy years after Independence,
India is still far from being one nation in
agriculture.
REFERENCES:
1. Chapagain, A. K., & Hoekstra, A. Y. (2008). The global component of freshwater demand
and supply: an assessment of virtual water flows between nations as a result of trade in
agricultural and industrial products. Water international, 33(1), 19-32.
2. Costinot, A., & Donaldson, D. (2011). How Large Are the Gains from Economic Integration?
Theory and Evidence from US Agriculture, 1880-2002. Massachusetts Institute of
Technology. Mimeo.
3. Donaldson, D., & Hornbeck, R. (2013). Railroads and American Economic Growth: A”
Market Access” Approach (No. w19213). National Bureau of Economic Research.
4. Goswami, Prashant, and Shiv Narayan Nishad. “Virtual water trade and time scales for loss
of water sustainability: A comparative regional analysis.” Scientific Reports 5 (2015).
5. Kathage, J., & Qaim, M. (2012). Economic impacts and impact dynamics of Bt (Bacillus
thuringiensis) cotton in India. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences , 109(29),
11652-11656.
6. Niti Aayog (2015), “Raising Agricultural Productivity and Making Farming Remunerative
for Farmers”.
7. Paul, S., Vijayaragavan, K., Singh, P., & Burman, R. R. (2015). Research productivity of
agricultural scientists: Evidences from high performing and low performing institutes. The
Indian Journal of Agricultural Sciences , 85(4).
8. Stads, G.J. 2015. “A snapshot of agricultural research investment and capacity in Asia.”
ASTI Resource Paper for the Asia Pacific Association of Agricultural Research Institutions’
High Level Policy Dialogue, Bangkok, December 2015. Washington, DC: International
Food Policy Research Institute.
9. Tamboli, P. M., & Nene, Y. L. (2013). Modernizing higher agricultural education system in
India to meet the challenges of 21st century. In XI Agricultural Science Congress held on
February.
Agriculture: More from Less
Mother and Child
05
IntroductIon: Invest Ing In
t
omorrow’s Ind Ia today
5.1 Imagine the government were an
investor trying to maximise India’s long-run
economic growth. Given constraints on fiscal
space and the state’s capacity to deliver public
services, where would it invest? This chapter
argues that some of the highest economic
returns to public investment in human capital
in India lie in maternal and early-life health
and nutrition interventions
1.
5.2 We begin by investigating the macro
relationship between infant health and
economic growth. For a sample of countries that have experienced rapid economic growth,
Figure 1 plots the relationship between GDP
growth and infant mortality in the year the
economy “took off”. It shows that countries
with better maternal and infant health “at take-
off” grew faster over the subsequent 20 years.
This relationship is robust and consistent with
other evidence
2.
5.3 Economists agree that human capital—
physical health, education, skills and broader
capabilities—is a key determinant of a
country’s growth potential. The government’s
investment in skills training—through
schemes like the Deen Dayal Uphadyay
1 Of there are course intrinsic reasons to invest in early-life health; it improves quality of life directly and expands
possibilities for the individual. But this chapter shows that, just on very narrow economic grounds alone, there
is a strong case for investing in early-life health.
2 Notably Bloom and Canning (2000) and Deaton (2013).
Imagine the government were an investor trying to maximise India's long-run
economic growth. Given fiscal and capacity constraints, where would it invest?
This chapter shows that relatively low-cost maternal and early-life health and
nutrition programs offer very high returns on investment because: (i) the most rapid
period of physical and cognitive development occurs in the womb, so in utero and
early-life health conditions significantly affect outcomes in adulthood; and (ii) the
success of subsequent interventions—schooling and training—are influenced by
early-life development. Despite recent progress, India generally under-performs
on maternal and child health indicators: pre-pregnancy weights and weight-gain
during pregnancy are both low. India is already halfway through its demographic
dividend, and taking full advantage requires a healthy and educated population.
Making these investments in maternal nutrition and sanitation, and enhancing
their effectiveness by working to change social norms, can help India exploit this
window.
CHAPTER
85
3 Colours classify countries by continent. Blue dots represent Africa, yellow Asia and green South America.
4 Currie and Vogl (2013).
5 Currie and Almond (2011).
6 Currie (2013).
7 Heckman (2014).
Grameen Kaushalya Yojana—tertiary
education, and schooling should all thus be
seen as investments in the productivity of
tomorrow’s worker.
5.4 But tomorrow’s worker is today’s child
or foetus, and evidence from epidemiology
and economics suggest that events which
occur while a child is in utero (in the womb)
or very young (below the age of 2) cast a
long shadow over cognitive development
and health status even in adulthood
4. Two
reasons explain the extraordinary persistence
of early-life conditions. First, the most rapid
period of physical and cognitive development
in a person’s life occurs in the womb, and
epidemiological evidence suggests that
a mother’s health and nutritional status
significantly affect the biological development
of the foetus
5. Economic research suggests
that health hazards—influenza epidemics,
being born in a low-rainfall year, polluted
air—during the in utero period may thus be
particularly difficult to recover from
6. Second, there may be “dynamic complementarities” in
human capital accumulation, because early-
life conditions affect cognitive development
7.
A healthy mother is more likely to give birth to
a healthy baby who learns better and stays on
in school longer as a result. Thus “skill begets
skill”, as Nobel Laureate James Heckman
wrote. Indeed, medical research has shown
that low birth-weight children benefit less
from early-life cognitive stimulus programs,
suggesting that dynamic complementarities
may kick in quite early in life. Figure 2
illustrates these interactions between maternal,
early-life and later-life human capital.
5.5 Figures 3 and 4 show a meta-analysis
depicting how the returns to human capital
investments vary with the age of the child.
Each dot in the graph is an estimate from
a research paper examining a program
or event’s long-run impact on cognitive
ability or test scores (Figure 3, measured in
standard deviations) and adult wages (Figure
4, measured in percentage terms). Certain
Figure 1: Infant mortality at “take-off” and average growth over the next 20 years3
Source: World Bank and Demographic and Health Surveys.
Mother and Child
86
Figure 2: Human Capital Accumulation and the Demographic Dividend
Figures 3 and 4: Returns to human capital investment by age of
child – what does the evidence say?
programs are labelled to give an idea of the
human capital investment programs that
are targeted at various ages. Two things are
noticeable from the graphs: first, returns to investment appear highest for programs that
target young children and in-utero health.
This is consistent with a large literature,
not least the work of Nobel Laureate James
Source: Ministry of Finance calculations.
Economic Survey 2015-16
87
8 See in particular Heckman (2013) for a review of literature on the downward-sloping return on human capital
investment by age.
9 See Currie and Vogl (2013) for an excellent review of the literature.
10 Bloom and Williamson (1998) and Bloom, Canning, and Malaney (2000)
11 A child’s “net nutrition” is defined as the sum total of (i) the nutrition available from the mother in the womb and
during breastfeeding, (ii) the quantity and quality of the food that c\
omplements breast milk from 6-24 months,
and (iii) energy losses due to disease and infection, and poor absorption of nutrients\
.
age population share will continue rising till
about 2035-2040, meaning that India has
another 25 years—one more generation—to
exploit this dividend. Demography in other
words is opportunity not destiny.
the state of (chIld’s) Play In IndIa
5.7 Height is a good proxy for early-
life conditions, and a predictor of later-life
outcomes, because both height and cognitive
development are partly determined by early-
life environment and net nutrition
11. Figure
5 shows height-for-age scores over time
in urban and rural India. Three things are
noteworthy: first, there has been improvement
over time in both urban and rural India:
children surveyed during the RSOC 2013-
14 round are on average taller than those
surveyed during NFHS 2005-06. Second,
there is a persistent rural-urban height gap
which has not closed over the past decade.
Third, despite the progress made, India
remains a negative outlier—our children are
Figure 5: Height-for-age in urban (left) and rural (right) India
Source: National Family Health Survey (NFHS-3) and Rapid Survey of Children 2013-14.
Heckman8. Second, programs targeting
younger children also appear relatively
cheap in comparison to investments made
in older children. Iodine supplementation is
relatively cheaper compared to improving
teacher quality or re-designing institutions to
raise school accountability, and also arguably
requires less service delivery capacity from
the state. As such, on both the benefit and
the cost side, early-life investments represent
a real opportunity for fiscal and capacity-
constrained governments
9.
5.6 It is timely to discuss how India should
allocate its human capital investments,
because she is currently in the middle of her
demographic dividend—a period of time
when population changes give economic
growth a boost by expanding the working-
age share of the population. Research
has suggested that capitalising on the
demographic dividend accounted for one-
third of the East Asian growth miracle
10.
Projections suggest that India’s working-
Mother and Child
88
on average 2 standard deviations shorter than
the healthy average.
5.8 These indications of poor early-
life health have later-life human capital
consequences. Most countries show a
height-cognitive development gradient
12, but
Figure 6 shows that it is particularly steep in
India—twice as steep as in the US in fact
13.
Two things stand out from Figure 6
14. First,
taller Indian children are considerably better
readers than shorter ones: the fraction of boys
able to read increase by from 40 to 60 per cent
as height goes from 115 to 135 centimetres.
This gradient has also been relatively stable
over time. Second, the levels—absolute
reading ability has not increased over time.
the state of maternal health
5.9 A child’s first 1000 days on earth are
thought to be a “critical period” of physical
and cognitive development with long-run
consequences. A child’s life chances during
this period are ultimately dependent on his or her mother. The main causes of mortality
in the first month of life differ substantially
from the determinants of demise in the
subsequent 11 months. Neonatal mortality—
the number of infants that die in the first
30 days of life—is an important indicator
of in utero nutrition. Relative to its level of
economic development, India has a high
neonatal mortality rate. Out of all the infants
who die in India, 70 per cent die in the first
month. A leading cause of this is low birth
weight. Babies with low birth weight are
more prone to dying in the first few days of
life
15; and women who begin pregnancy too
thin and who do not gain enough weight
during pregnancy are far more likely to have
low birth weight babies who die in the first
few days of life than women who are better
nourished during pregnancy.
16
5.10 Data
17 suggests that 42.2 per cent
of Indian women are underweight at the
beginning of pregnancy. By contrast,
only 35 per cent of non-pregnant women
12 See Deaton (2007), Schick (2010), Paxson (2008).
13 Spears (2011).
14 The flattening of the lines for girls at the bottom of the height distribution may merely reflect statistical noise, as
fewer than 5% of measured 10 year old girls were less than 107 centimetr\
es tall; allowing for a quadratic term
does not improve the fit of a linear regression.
15 See Ota et al (2011).
16 A woman is considered to be underweight if her body mass index, or weight\
in kilograms divided by her height
in meters, squared, is less than 18.5.
17 From the Demographic and Health Surveys.
Figure 6: Height and cognitive development are positively correlated
Girls Boys
Source: Indian Human Development Survey (IHDS) 2005 and 2012.
Economic Survey 2015-16
89
18 All numbers in the paragraph are based on Coffey (2015).
19 When compared across the same ages, till about age 35, fraction of underweight women exceeds that of men by
at least 5 percentage points.
20 See Coffey, Khera and Spears (2013).
of childbearing age are underweight. So
pregnant women are perversely more likely
to be underweight. Not only are Indian
women too thin when they begin pregnancy,
they also do not gain enough weight during
pregnancy to compensate for low pre-
pregnancy body mass. Women in India gain
only about 7 kilograms during pregnancy,
which is substantially less than the 12.5-
18 kg gain that the WHO recommends for
underweight women
18.
5.11 Figure 7 depicts weight gain during
pregnancy against initial weight for a sample
of developing countries. The figure shows
that lighter women generally gain more
weight during pregnancy Despite recent
progress, Indian women have relatively low
pre-pregnancy weights compared with other
countries, and should be expected to gain
more weight during pregnancy. Figure 8
shows initial weight and during-pregnancy
weight gain across 3 wealth terciles, plotted
against number of months pregnant. Women
from richer households in India start
pregnancy heavier, but do not gain more
weight during pregnancy. This suggests that resources are at least part of the reason for
low pre-pregnancy weight.
5.12
Another reason for poor maternal
health is that social norms accord young
women low status in joint households. It is
telling that we see much higher underweight
rates for young women than older men—40
per cent of young women are underweight
while only 25 per cent of middle-aged men
are. These within-household nutritional
differentials are stark19. A recent study shows
that children of younger brothers in joint
family households are significantly more
likely to be born underweight than children
of their older brother. This is attached in part
to the lower status of younger daughter-in-
laws in families
20.
ImProvIng maternal health In IndIa
5.13 Given that maternal health casts a
long shadow on an individual’s cognitive
development and life chances, investing in
maternal health could become a top policy
priority of the government. The National Food
Security Act of 2013 legislated a universal
cash entitlement for pregnant women of at
Figure 7: Pregnancy weight gain with respect to similar countries
Source: Demographic and Health Surveys and Rapid Survey of Children
Mother and Child
90
Source: Rapid Survey of Children 2013-14.
least 6,000 rupees. This program presents
a promising opportunity to help improve
nutrition during pregnancy, a problem which
affects both urban and rural women, and the
middle-class and the poor.
5.14 If pregnant women receive cash
payments from the government, and if
families convert these payments into more,
higher-quality food and more rest for pregnant
women, maternity entitlements will improve
infants' birth weights. This would have lasting
benefits for health and human capital.
5.15 However, getting government funds
into the hands of pregnant women is not a
straightforward task, nor is it certain that the
extra cash will be converted into more, better
food and rest. Therefore, the cash transfer
could be paired with education about how
much weight a woman should gain during
pregnancy and why weight gain during
pregnancy is important. The cash transfer
should be given in a single, lump-sum
payment early in pregnancy to avoid delays,
reduce administrative costs, and ensure that
it is possible for the household to spend the money on better food during pregnancy.
5.16
Is it doable? In a recently conducted
study in 261 (treatment) villages women were
provided conditional cash transfers (CCTs)
of R250 at the end of every month.
21 While
easy to monitor aspects such as attendance
at village health, sanitation and nutrition
days, and weight gain during pregnancy
and child weight monitoring showed a
significant increase in treatment value to the
tune of 30 percent, behavioural patterns like
breast-feeding, corrective treatment during
diarrhoea were around 4-5 percent. With
careful design and significant investment
of state capacity, maternal health could be
significantly improved during pregnancy.
Disease Externalities: Open defecation
5.17 A growing literature in development
economics is documenting the importance of
exposure to disease in early life. In one well
known example, Hoyt Bleakley has studied
the effects of the eradication of hookworm
from the historical United States, when it
more closely resembled today’s developing
countries. Bleakley found that children who
21 Conducted by Oxford Policy Management and shared with the Ministry of Finance.
Figure 8: Weight and weight gain within India by wealth of household
Economic Survey 2015-16
91
benefited from a sanitation and hookworm
treatment campaign went on to learn more in
school and to grow into adults who earned
more income.
5.18 There are a host of disease externalities
one must closely consider including drinking
water, sanitation and air pollution amongst
others. This section considers one of the
biggest problems hurting early-life health in
today’s India: enteric infection due to open
defecation.
The problem of open defecation
5.19 One significant and internationally
unique source of early life disease in India is
open defecation, especially in rural India. As
Table 1 documents, open defecation in India
is much more common than in even much
poorer countries. India has the largest rural
open defecation rate in South Asia by a very
large margin. It is interesting to note that in
Bangladesh open defecation has almost been
fully eliminated.
Table 1: Open defecation in India from the South Asian perspective
Rural open
defecation
(2015, Per cent) GDP per capita
(2013, World Bank)
India 61.31,498
Nepal 37.5694
Pakistan 21.41,275
Afghanistan 17.4665
Bhutan 3.82,363
Bangladesh 1.8958
Sri Lanka 03,280
Source: Hathi et al (2014).
5.20 According to WHO and UNICEF Joint
Monitoring Programme estimates, 61 per
cent of rural Indians defecate in the open in
2015, compared with only 32 per cent of rural
people in sub-Saharan Africa. Even sanitation
laggards perform better than India, with 17
per cent rural open defecation in Afghanistan
and 15 per cent in Kenya. Moreover, many people in rural India who live in households
that contain working latrines that are in use
by other household members nevertheless
defecate in the open.
5.21
These facts indicate that income
constraints may not be the main determinant
of open defecation. Research suggests that
rural Indian households reject the types
of latrines promoted by the World Health
Organization and the Indian government
partly because their pits needed to be emptied
every few years. Latrine pit emptying, which
is routine in other countries, is substantially
complicated by rural India's history of
untouchability- work of disposing of human
faeces is associated with severe forms of
social exclusion and oppression.
5.22 Open defecation spreads germs into the
environment, and therefore makes growing
children sick. One form of this sickness is
diarrhoea, which robs growing children of
the food that they eat. Another resulting
disease could be environmental enteropathy,
a chronic inflammatory response of the
intestines to repeated exposure to the germs
spread by open defecation; it reduces the
ability of children’s intestines from absorbing
nutrition
22.
5.23 In fact, the consequences of open
defecation for Indian children may be
worsened by high population density than
simple international comparisons may
suggest. Figure 9 presents new evidence of
this important association; the problem of
child stunting is worse in villages where a
higher percentage defecate in the open. It
plots the height for age indicator against the
fraction of village that defecates in the open.
The gap between red (dashed) and the blue
(solid) line is the private health benefit of a
toilet: households who do not defecate in the
open have higher height-for-age scores than
households who openly defecate, no matter
the village's level of open defecation. The
22 See Korpe (2012).
Mother and Child
92
downward slope of both lines shows that as
the number of people who openly defecate in
the village increases, height-for-age indicator
falls further below its healthy level. There
sharpest falls in height-for-age are seen as
the fraction of village households who openly
defecate approaches 100 per cent. This is an
example of a social externality.
Addressing open defecation
5.24 All this evidence points to the vital
importance of the Prime Minister’s Swachh
Bharat Mission, which has raised the profile
of the pressing problem of open defecation
especially in rural India, and has committed
to ending it as quickly. In the last year alone,
the government built over 80 lakh toilets.
Similarly, the UN’s Sustainable Development
Goals commit to ending open defecation
worldwide by 2030. The success of these
goals will naturally depend largely on the
pace of reduction in open defecation in rural
India, because this is where most people who
defecate in the open live.
5.25 Historically, open defecation in India
has declined by about one percentage point
per year. If the Sustainable Development Goal of eliminating open defecation by 2030
is going to be met, this historical rate of
decline must be more than tripled, and that
acceleration must be sustained over fifteen
years. It is clear that this represents a major
challenge.
5.26
Evidence from a variety of sources
shows that the next challenge in rural India is
behavioural
23. Going forward, it is important
to understand barriers to toilet adoption in
rural India and promote latrine use.
conclusIon: what other hIgh-
r
eturn Investments can the
g
overnment make?
5.27 Early life interventions can be an
important policy tool for improving the health
and human capital of the Indian population,
and in this way be a critical investment in
long-run economic growth. A big challenge
here as in many other instances is deeply
entrenched norms and facilitating behavioural
change. One can build clinics in villages or
transfer money to pregnant mothers or build
latrines, but how does one bring out the right
usage of all this physical capital is the next
Source: Rapid Survey of Children (2013-14).
23 A salient lesson of the SQUAT survey (squatreport.in) is that achieving latrine use requires behaviour change.
A large scale randomized trail by Water and Sanitation Program in Madhya Pradesh (http://www.wsp.org/
sites/wsp.org/files/publications/WSP-India-Madhya-Pradesh-IE-Research-Brief.pdf) documents substantial
increments of latrine use through education and information.
Figure 9: Early-life health is worse is areas of high open defecation.
Economic Survey 2015-16
93
task in front of the government.
5.28 Two such interventions are already
part of the government’s policy agenda –
providing food to pregnant mothers under the
National Food Security Act and addressing
open defecation via the Swachh Bharat
Mission. Table 2 shows interventions that
have been supported by rigorous evidence to
significantly improve maternal and early-life
health.
5.29 The breastfeeding example illustrates
how some investments by the state can lead
to tangible changes in changing norms in a
relatively short period of time. Government
action has significantly raised the percentage of mothers who exclusively breastfeed their
children during the first 6 months of life.
This has been due to programmes like the
Janani Suraksha Yojana and other schemes
under the Integrated Child Development
Scheme that are delivered via Anganwadi
programmes. The proportion of breast
feeding mothers is now 62 per cent, with the
largest improvements in the worst states.
5.30
The government has recognised the
importance of influencing social norms in
a wide variety of sectors—persuading the
rich to give up subsidies they do not need,
reducing social prejudices against girls,
educating people about the health externalities
Table 2: High Impact Interventions
Stage Intervention Reason
Pre-pregnancy Folic acid supplementation
Improves maternal nutrition, reducing low
birth-weight and neonatal mortality
During pregnancy
Calcium supplementation
During pregnancy Protein supplementation
Pre-pregnancy Compulsory iodising of salt Reduces stunting
Postnatal Encouragement to breastfeed Reduces neonatal and post neonatal
mortality
Postnatal Vitamin A supplementation
Reduces infant mortality
Postnatal Zinc supplementation and treatment
for diarrhoea
Postnatal Deworming Reduces stunting and wasting
Figure 10: Changes in breastfeeding rates over the past decade, Per cent
Source: World Bank.
Mother and Child
94
of defecating in the open, and encouraging
citizens to keep public spaces clean. The
government has a progressive role to play in
changing norms, and indeed governments all
over the world have embarked on systematic
ways of studying how to promote behavioural
change. Creating such a Nudge unit within
government as other countries have done
may be a useful way of taking this agenda
forward.
references
Barro, Robert (2001). “Human Capital:
Growth, History and Policy- A Session
to Honor Stanley Engerman,” American
Economic Review P&P , Vol. 91 (2), pp. 12-
17.
Bharadwaj, Prashant, Katrine Loken, and
Christopher Neilson. “Early Life Health
Interventions and Academic Achievement.”
American Economic Review , Vol. 103 (5), pp.
1862–91.
Bloom, David and David Canning (2000).
“The Health and Wealth of Nations,” Science,
Vol. 287 (5646), pp. 1207-1209.
Case, Anne, and Christina Paxson (2008).
“Stature and Status: Height, Ability, and
Labor Market Outcomes.” The Journal of
Political Economy Vol. 116 (3), pp. 499–532.
Coffey, Diane (2015). “Prepregnancy Body
Mass and Weight Gain during Pregnancy in
India and Sub-Saharan Africa,” Proceedings
of the National Academy of Sciences , Vol.
112 (11) (March 17, pp. 3302–7.
Coffey, D, Payal Hathi, Lovey Pant, Sabrina
Haque and Dean Spears (2015), Demography.
Coffey, Diane, Reetika Khera and Dean
Spears (2013). “Women’s status and
children’s height in India: Evidence from
joint rural households,” Working Paper.
Currie, Janet and Tom Vogl (2013). “Early
Life Health and Adult Circumstance in
Developing Countires,” Annual Review of
Economics, Vol. 5, pp. 1-36.
Deaton, Angus (2007). “Height, Health, and
Development,” Proceedings of the National
Academy of Sciences , Vol. 104 (33), pp.
13232–37.
Deaton, Angus (2013). The Great Escape:
Health, Wealth and the Origins of Inequality .
Princeton University Press.
Jayachandran, Seema, and Rohini Pande
(2015). “Why Are Indian Children So
Short?” Working Paper, National Bureau of
Economic Research, http://www.nber.org/
papers/w21036.
Korpe, Poonum S., and William A. Petri
(2012). “Environmental Enteropathy:
Critical Implications of a Poorly Understood
Condition,” Trends in Molecular Medicine ,
Vol. 18 (6), pp. 328–36.
Ota, Erika, Megumi Haruna, Motoi Suzuki,
Dang Duc Anh, Le Huu Tho, Nguyen Thi
Thanh Tam, Vu Dinh Thiem, et al (2011).
“Maternal Body Mass Index and Gestational
Weight Gain and Their
Association with Prenatal Outcomes in
Viet Nam,” Bulletin of the World Health
Organization, Vol. 89 (2), pp. 127–36.
Romer, Paul, (1990). “Endogenous
Technological Change,” Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 99 (5), 71-102.
Schick, Andreas, and Richard H. Steckel
(2010). “Height as a Proxy for Cognitive
and Non-Cognitive Ability ,” Working Paper,
National Bureau of Economic Research,
http://www.nber.org/papers/w16570
Spears, Dean (2012). “Height and cognitive
achievement among Indian children,”
Economics and Human Biology , Vol. 10 (2),
pp. 210-219.
The Million Death Study Collaborators
(2010). “Causes of Neonatal and Child
Mortality in India: Nationally Representative
Mortality Survey.” Lancet 376, no. 9755, pp.
1853–60.
World Health Organization (2004).
“Appropriate Body-Mass Index for Asian
Populations and Its Implications for Policy
and Intervention Strategies.” The Lancet 363,
9403, pp. 157–63.
Economic Survey 2015-16
Bounties for the Well-Off
06
IntroductIon
6.1 The government spends nearly 4.2 per
cent of GDP
1 subsidising various commodities
and services. Public discussion of these
subsidies focuses on their importance in
the economic lives of the poor. This chapter
shows that the Indian state’s generosity is not
restricted to its poorest citizens. In fact, in many
cases, the beneficiaries are disproportionately
the well-off. In at least one area – corporate
taxes – the government has recently taken
decisive action, by identifying and quantifying
exemptions amounting to about R 62,000 crore
2
and announcing a clear path for phasing them
out. A move to GST would also eliminate
leakages due to rationalisation of indirect tax exemptions estimated to cost R
3.3 lakh crore.
3
These commendable efforts could be extended
to other areas where the poor and vulnerable
are not exposed.
6.2 The aim of this chapter is to document
some of this largesse, in areas that often attract
policy attention. Our list is neither exhaustive
in scope, nor precise in its estimates. But it
nonetheless allows a broad understanding of
how much government subsidises the better-
off.
6.3 We focus on seven areas: small savings
schemes, kerosene, railways, electricity, LPG,
gold, and aviation turbine fuel (ATF). In each
case, we highlight salient facts and estimate
the subsidy’s magnitude.
1 Economic Survey 2014-15, Vol. 1, Chapter 3.
2 This is projected number for 2014-15 as per budget 2015-16.
3 Subramanian Committee Report on the Revenue Neutral Rate and Structure of Rates for the Goods and Services
Tax (GST), available at http://finmin.nic.in/the_ministry/dept_revenue/Report_Revenue_Neutral_Rate.pdf. The
exemption amount is calculated as 2.7 per cent of GDP at current market price for the year 2014-15.
Subsidies for the poor tends to attract policy attention. But a number of policies
provide benefits to the well-off. We estimate these benefits for the small savings
schemes and the tax/subsidy policies on cooking gas, railways, power, aviation
turbine fuel, gold and kerosene, making assumptions about the definition of
“well-off” and the nature of neutral policies. We find that together these schemes
and policies provide a bounty to the well-off of about R1 lakh crore. We highlight
that policies that are based on providing tax incentives will, in India, benefit
not the middle class but those at the very top end of the income distribution.
For example, the average income of those in the 20 percent tax bracket places
them roughly in the 98.4
th percentile of the Indian income distribution, and the
corresponding figure for the 30 percent tax bracket is the 99.5
th percentile.
CHAPTER
96
Table 1: Characteristics of savings schemes
SchemeTax
Treatment ($)Compound
-
ing of Interest 2011-12@
2012-13@ 2013-14@ Interest
Rate*
Post Office Savings Account TTT**Yearly 868.4921.9953.44.0%
Post Office Savings Time
Deposit## TTT
Quarterly 470.9531.9 611.68.4%
Post Office 5-year Time Deposit ETEQuarterly 10.518.521.78.5%
Post Office Monthly Income
Account Scheme TTT
Monthly 284.2190.5179.98.4%
Senior Citizen Savings Scheme ETEQuarterly 37.222.823.59.3%
5 Years National Savings
Certificate (VIII Issue) ETE
Half yearly 103.3191.0167.28.5%
10 Years National Savings
Certificate (IX Issue) ETE
Half yearly 0.019.6 35.68.8%
15 year Public Provident Fund
Account EEE
Yearly 366.6443.6506.78.7%
Tax Free Bonds # TET- 61.034.9144.07.6%
Notes:
$ The tax treatment of any scheme has three stages- first at the time of deposit, second on the interest accrued on the deposits,
and third at the time of withdrawal. For example, under an EEE scheme deposits, interest accrued, and withdrawal of money
are all tax exempt.
* Interest rates are for the year 2014-15.
** Any scheme which attracts tax at the first stage (at the time of contribution) is deemed as taxed at the time of withdrawal.
## Includes post office 1-year, 2-year, 3-year time deposit and 5 year recurring deposits.
@ Amount is gross deposit in R Billion.
# Interest rate on NHAI 15Y bond of 2015-16.
“SMALL” Savings
6.4 “Small” savings schemes were initially
created to mobilise saving by encouraging
“small earners” to save, and offered above-
market deposit rates in accessible locations
like post offices for this purpose. Recent
discussions have focused on one efficiency
cost of “small” savings schemes – how they
hinder monetary policy transmission. Because
small savings schemes offer high and fixed
deposit rates (within year) and compete with
banks, it is difficult for banks to reduce their
own deposit rates and hence pass on policy
rate cuts to consumers in form of lower lending
rates. Recently, the government has reduced
rates on some small savings schemes to make
them more responsive to market conditions.
6.5 But questions also arise about the equity
of small savings schemes: what is the rate
offered on these instruments, who benefits
from them, and how large are these implicit
subsidies? These findings are highlighted in
Tables 1 and 2.
6.6 It is misleading to characterise these
savings schemes as “small”, because in fact there are at least three types of schemes, only
one of which can really qualify as “small.”
This first set of “actually small” schemes
ranges from postal deposits to schemes for the
elderly and women. The second set is of “not-
so-small” schemes, which includes the most
important of all – the Public Provident Fund
(PPF). And the third category is “not-small-at-
all” schemes, which includes tax-free bonds
issued by designated public sector companies
like IRCL, IIFCL, PFC, HUDCO, NHB, REC,
NTPC, NHPC, IREDA, NHAI and others,
supposedly to finance infrastructure projects.
6.7
The interest rates on most of these
schemes are fixed (for year), but they vary
in magnitude and periodicity. Whatever
the terms, the key determinant of their real
return is their tax treatment. Ideally, savings
schemes should be taxed according to the
“EET principle”. The first “E” stands for tax
exemption of the contribution, the second
E for exemption of interest income, while
T stands for taxation of the principal (and
interest) when it is withdrawn. The logic of
this principle is explained in the Box 1 at the
end of this section.
Economic Survey 2015-16
97
Table 2: Implicit Subsidies in Savings schemes
Outstanding as on 31st
March 2015 (in R crore) Interest
Rate* (%) Effective
Interest Rate** (%) Comparable
Market
instrument rate (%) Implicit
subsidy rate @Implicit
Subsidy (in R crore) ^
Actually Small Post office Saving Account 474224.04.0 4.00.0% 0
Not-So-Small
PPF 3195498.716.0 10.06.0%11900 (##)
Not-Small-at-All
Tax Free bonds (2011-
12/2015-16) # 2997
7.613.7 10.03.7% 111
Notes:
* Rate of interest is for the year 2014-15.
** The effective interest rate is the internal rate of return (IRR) on the scheme after incorporating the impact of tax treatment
on the deposit and interest accrued. The assumed average tax rate for the IRR calculation is 15 per cent.
$ Comparable market instrument is saving account deposits in the case of post office savings and 15 year G-Sec in the case
of PPF and tax free bonds.
@ Implicit subsidy rate is difference between the effective interest rate and comparable market instrument.
^ Implicit subsidy is the subsidy rate multiplied by the outstanding balance of the scheme as of 31st March 2015.
# Interest rate on 2015-16 NHAI 15-year bond.
## As per income tax return data, around 62 per cent of 80C claims are from the people who have gross income greater than
R4 lakh, therefore the implicit subsidy to well-off for PPF is 62 per cent multiplied by R19182 ( which is 6 per cent
multiplied by outstanding amount in PPF).
6.8 Most schemes in the “actually small”
category are TTT – neither the interest nor
the contribution to the scheme are exempt
from tax under Section 80C
4 of the Income
Tax Act. By contrast, the PPF, which is a
“not-so-small” scheme is EEE: the interest is
tax exempt, contributions are tax exempt, but
up to a limit of R 1.5 lakhs, and tax exempt
at the time of withdrawal. Finally, schemes
in the “not small at all” category are TET –
the contribution is taxable but the interest is
tax exempt and there are no limits (unless
otherwise indicated at the time, they are
issued) on the permissible subscription to
these bonds.
6.9 The effect of all these special treatments
can be summarised into one metric—the
effective rate of return on these instruments
compared with the return on a comparable
savings instrument, say saving account
deposits in the case of post office savings, and 15-year G-Sec in the case of PPF and
tax-free bonds. Table 2 shows that the return
on PPF contributions and tax-free bonds are
particularly high (Table 2).
6.10
We can indirectly infer how well-off
beneficiaries of the PPF scheme are. Roughly
62 per cent of total 80C deductions in FY
2013-14 were accounted for by taxpayers
with gross taxable income more than R4 lakh
(47 per cent by those earning more than R5
lakh). These individuals are at the 97.3
rd and
98.4
th percentiles of the income distribution
respectively – hardly “small”.
6.11 While not all 80C deductions are PPF
deposits, they appear very sensitive to 80C
contribution rules. In 2014-15, when the
limit for the 80C deductions was increased
by R 50,000 there was an almost a one to one
increase in 80C claims for those in the 20
and 30 per cent tax brackets (Figure-1A and
B). From independent data from State Bank
4 80C is a section in Income tax Act of India, which allows deduction from Gross Income for various savings
schemes.
Bounties for the Well-Off
98
Source: Department of Revenue
of India, we found that this increase was
associated with increases in PPF deposits.
6.12 In sum, the effective returns to PPF
deposits are very high, creating a large
implicit subsidy which accrues mostly to
taxpayers in the top income brackets. The
magnitude of this implicit subsidy is about 6
percentage points – approximately R12,000
crore in fiscal cost terms.
6.13 The interest subsidy on tax-free bonds
is slightly smaller—about 3.7 percentage
points—but because there are no limits on
permissible contributions (other than that
dictated by the supply of such instruments),
the main beneficiaries are large savers who
can set aside large amounts. For example,
the average size of the investment in tax-free
bonds by the individuals was nearly R 6 lakhs
in FY 2013-14, which was six times the total
exemption limit under Section 80C.
6.14 In light of a number of tax incentives
for savings given to individuals it is worth
asking how wealthy they are in relative
terms. So, we identify the tax thresholds for
the 10, 20 and 30 percent tax bracket which were 2, 5, and 10 lakhs, respectively in FY
2013-14. We then compute the average
incomes of the people in these tax brackets
were and see where they stood in the overall
income distribution (Figure 6.2). The results
are striking. In 2013-14, the average income
in the 30 percent threshold was R24.7 lakhs
and these earners were roughly 25 lakhs in
number (1.1 percent of all taxpayers) and
placed in the top 0.5 percent of the overall
Indian income distribution. Similarly, the
54 lakh income earners in the 20 percent tax
bracket represented the top 1.6 percent of the
Indian income distribution.
6.15
These numbers are striking and have
one policy implication: any tax incentives that
are given, for example, for savings, benefit
not the middle class, not the upper middle
class but the super- rich who represent the top
1-2 percent of the Indian income distribution.
Now, it is by definition true that top taxpayers
will be beneficiaries of tax incentives.
However, in most countries, they will range
from being middle class to very rich. In India,
they are the super-rich.
Economic Survey 2015-16
99
Box 6.1: Tax Treatment of Savings
Income tax is inherently biased against savings; it leads to double taxation in so far both the savings and the
earnings are taxed. In general, the tax system provides for a mechanism to eliminate this bias and promote
savings in the economy. This mechanism takes the form of a tax incentive by way of a deduction for contribution
to specified savings instruments. In India, savings in several instruments are further incentivised by exempting
fully, or partially, the earnings at the accumulation stage as well as the withdrawals from tax (both the contribution
and the earnings). In effect, savings are subject to exempt-exempt-exempt (EEE) method of taxation i.e. they are
exempt at all three stages of contribution, accumulation and withdrawal.\
The case for concessional tax treatment of savings is built on the consideration that a tax concession for savings
leads to higher post-tax return for the investor. The higher returns, in turn, create a positive substitution effect
whereby, in favour of savings rather than current consumption. However, what is missed out is the fact that it also
creates a disincentive for savings (income effect), since the higher returns now require lower savings to meet the
lifetime savings target.
There is some empirical evidence to suggest that the positive and the negative effects are neutralized at the economy
level. Further, the tax incentives for savings, as designed in India, do not encourage net savings (contr\
ibution
plus accumulation minus withdrawals) since withdrawals are also exempt from tax. In addition, national savings
comprise of household savings, government savings and corporate savings. To the extent, tax incentives for
savings lead to fiscal loss, government savings are adversely impacted, thereby partially neutralizing the increase
in household savings.
Further, tax incentives for savings distort the interest structure and choice of saving instrume\
nts, and merely
help mobilize funds to specified savings instruments. They also increase the interest rate at which households
are willing to lend funds to banks (i.e., make deposits) , thereby adversely affecting investment. They are also
regressive in as much as they provide relatively higher tax benefits to investors in the higher tax bracket; in fact,
the real “small savers”, who are largely outside the tax net, do not enjoy any form of tax subsidy on their \
savings.
Overall, tax incentives for savings, more so as designed in India, are economically inefficient, inequitable and
do not serve the intended purpose. Hence, there is a strong case for review of the design of the tax incentives for
savings schemes.
While there should be no tax incentive for savings, the question is what should be the tax treatment of savings
so as to eliminate the inherent bias under income tax. The emerging wisdom is that savings should be taxed only
at the point of contribution (TEE) or withdrawal (EET); the latter being the best international practice on several
counts.
First, savings (contribution) reduce cash flow and therefore, the ‘ability’ to pay. Therefore, taxation at the point of
contribution would create hardship and act as a disincentive to save. However, taxation at the point of withdrawal
Contd....
Bounties for the Well-Off
100
other BountIes
6.16 For a number of commodities including
gold, LPG, kerosene, electricity, railway
fares, aviation turbine fuel, we have calculated
the implicit subsidy or tax rates. We define
the “poor” as those whose consumption is
in the bottom three deciles (lowest 30 per
cent) of the population, and the “better off”
as the rest
5, except in case of electricity and
railways where this classification is different.
Gold
6.17 Gold is a strong demerit good: the ‘rich’
consume most of it (the top 20 per cent of
population account for roughly 80 per cent of
total consumption) and the poor spend almost
negligible fraction of their total expenditure on it. Yet gold is only taxed at about 1-1.6
per cent (States and Centre combined),
compared with tax of about 26 per cent for
normal goods (the central government’s
excise tax on gold is zero compared with
12.5 per cent for normal commodities.) In
other words, there is a huge subsidy of about
25 percentage points (the difference between
average tax on other commodities and tax
on gold). About 98 per cent of this subsidy
accrues to the better-off and only 2 per cent
to the bottom 3 deciles. And this is an under-
estimate because the data on consumption is
from the NSS, which is known not to capture
those at the very top end of the income and
expenditure distribution.
5 The decile classes in the population are calculated from 68th Household Consumer Expenditure Survey of NSS
(2011-12) data.
(principal or earnings) occurs when the ability to pay is greater and therefore, justified on principles of taxation.
Second, under the TEE method, taxation at the point of contribution does not provide any immediate incentive to
save nor does exemption of withdrawals discourage dissavings. However, under the EET method of taxation of
savings, full deduction from income at the point of contribution and accumulation acts as an incentive for savings
while taxation at the point of withdrawal penalizes dissavings. The combined effect is that it encourages the saver
to build a self-financing old age social security system.
Third, under the TEE method, there is no incentive for consumption smoothening since withdrawals are exempt
irrespective of the amount. However, the EET method allows for consumption smoothening particularly in old
age since taxation of withdrawals incentivizes postponement of consumption. Under a progressive personal
income tax rate structure, there is an in-built incentive to restrict withdrawals to meet necessary consumption only
since lower withdrawals imply taxation at lower marginal tax rate and hence, lower tax liability. Consequently,
the potential for old-age poverty is minimized.
Fourth, the EET method provides discretion to the saver for tax smoothening and minimiz\
e the tax liability
arising from any bunching of gains. Fifth, because taxation is at the last point in the savings process, there is no
uncertainty about the potential tax liability unlike in the case of TEE method where the saver is uncertain whether
the Government would impose a tax at the point of accumulation or withdrawal to raise revenue to overcome the
fiscal crisis.
Sixth, the EET method is extremely simple in terms of compliance and administration since it can be
operationalized by opening an account with a designated fund which, in turn, can invest in a mix of a broad range
of debt and equity instruments depending upon the risk appetite of the saver. All earnings are required to flow
into the same account and withdrawals, if any, can be subject to withholding tax. It does not require any complex
tracking mechanism to prevent leakage of revenue. It is not necessary for the saver to maintain details of savings
and earnings to claim tax benefit.
Finally, most developed countries and many developing countries are implementing the EET method of taxation
of savings.
In view of the foregoing, India should move, in a phased manner, to the EET method of taxation of savings.
Interestingly, the New Pension Scheme (NPS) is already being subjected to the EET method of taxation.
Therefore, deductions under Section 80C and 80CCD should be re-assessed to move toward a common EET
principle for tax savings.
Economic Survey 2015-16
101
6 Both of these have been calculated by the Ministry of Railways.
7 Petroleum Planning and Analysis Cell.
8 Consumption from 68th Household Consumer Expenditure Survey of NSS (2011-12).
9 The tax rate is a sum of centre’s excise duty and state taxes (average of state tax rates).
10 The tax rate is a sum of centre’s excise duty and state taxes (average of state tax rates).
Railway
6.18 There is a difference between the
subsidy for the better-off and the poor in
railways, because fares vary in different
classes of travel. We combine the categories
of A/C, first class, second class, sleeper as
the primary modes of rail travel by rich and
unreserved category as mode of travel used
primarily by the poor. We then compute the
implicit subsidy rate for these categories,
by comparing the actual fare charged to the
consumers with the marginal cost of supply
(i.e. difference between earning per km and
cost per km)
6. On this basis, the subsidy rate
(implicit subsidy as a ratio of actual cost of
journey to railways) amounts to 34 per cent
for the better-off and 69 per cent for the poor.
Note that there is no provision for covering
fixed costs, so the calculation understates,
perhaps significantly, the subsidy.
LPG
6.19 LPG consumers receive a subsidy of
R238.51 per 14.2 kg cylinder
7 (as in January
2016), which amounts to a subsidy rate of 36
per cent (ratio of subsidy amount to the market
price). It turns out that 91 per cent of these
subsidies are accounted for by the better-off
as their share of consumption of LPG in the
total consumption is about 91 per cent; while
the poor account for only 9 per cent of LPG
consumption and hence only 9 per cent of
subsidies go to them.
8 So, this subsidy, aimed
at benefitting the poor, is hardly being used
by them. Another important point to note is
that LPG is subsidized heavily, as compared
to other energy related commodities like
petrol, diesel etc which are taxed at very
high rates, hence the effective subsidy to the
better-off on account of LPG is much more than the actual direct subsidy of 36 per cent
(more details in next section).
Electricity
6.20 In the case of electricity, like railways,
tariffs vary on levels of consumption, so there
is
de facto targeting of the subsidy. Based on
data available for two states (Tamil Nadu
and Delhi), we have estimated the subsidy
for the better-off and poor by comparing the
average billing rate, which depends on levels
of consumption, with the average cost of
supply of power. Implicit subsidy rate is the
subsidy given per unit to domestic consumers
as a ratio of the cost of supply per unit. The
rates charged to the better-off are subsidized
to the extent of 32 per cent, and the poor, 49
per cent (average for Delhi and Tamil Nadu).
But given the magnitude of relative power
consumption of the better-off in the total
consumption of electricity (84 per cent), the
better-off appropriate a substantial amount of
the total subsidy.
ATF
6.21 Aviation fuel is taxed at about 20
percent (average of tax rates for all states),
while diesel and petrol are taxed at about
55 per cent
9 and 61 per cent10 (as in January
2016). The real consumers of ATF are those
who travel by air, who essentially are the well-
off. Hence there is an implicit subsidy for air
passengers (the difference between taxes on
diesel/petrol and aviation fuel) amounting to
about 30 percentage points.
Kerosene
6.22 There is a subsidy of R9.16/litre (as
in January 2016) on kerosene distributed
under the public distribution system, which
translates into a subsidy rate of about 38
Bounties for the Well-Off
102
per cent (subsidy per litre as a ratio of non-
subsidized market price per litter) for both
rich and poor. Kerosene makes up about 1 per
cent of the consumption basket of the poor;
however about 50 per cent of the Kerosene
given under PDS is consumed by the well-off
and the rest by the bottom 3 deciles, showing
that half of the subsidy benefit goes to the
well-off section.
6.23 We can combine all this information into
one comparative assessment of the bounties/
subsidies given by governments by invoking
two criteria: equity and effectiveness. Goods
that account for a large share of expenditures
of poorer households, such as food, will
typically be merit goods, and should therefore
be taxed at low rates, made exempt from
taxation, or even subsidized. Conversely,
from an equity perspective, if a large share
of expenditure on a good is by the better-off,
then the good should be taxed at higher rates.
6.24 But even if a good is a merit good,
warranting a low tax/exemption/subsidy,
policy makers will want to ask how effective
such a decision would be, based on how well
Source: NSS, PPAC,World Bank, Ministry of Railways
Notes:
Railways (Rich) and Electricity (Rich) denotes the subsidy rates on \
these for the well-off section of population.
The line drawn is a normative one to indicate that higher the benefit cost ratio, the lower is the case for subsidization or
low taxation of that commodity; however, tax systems opt for few rates on administrative grounds, hence the calculation of
implicit subsidies in the next section takes only two normative rates-higher rates on energy related commodities (due to negative
externalities) and a standard rate for all others.
targeted the implicit subsidy would be, where
the implicit subsidy is the difference between
allowing the targeted group to face a different
price from some notional market price. If the
poor also account for a large fraction of total
expenditure on the merit good, then the low
tax/subsidy will be well targeted; if, on the
other hand, they account for a small share of
the total expenditure of that good, then the
subsidy decision will come with the cost that
most of the benefits of the subsidy will accrue
to the relatively better off.
6.25 So, one can think of a commodity-
wise benefit-cost analysis for determining
the efficacy of government interventions on
taxes and subsidies. The benefit could be
thought of as the share of the subsidy going
to the target (poor) group. The cost is simply
that proportion that “leaks” to the non-target
group. More precisely, the benefit/cost ratio
is defined as a share of expenditure of that
commodity in the household budgets of the
poor, divided by the share of consumption of
that particular commodity by the non-target
group.
Economic Survey 2015-16
103
11 http://finmin.nic.in/the_ministry/dept_revenue/Report_Revenue_Neutral_Rate.pdf
Table 3: Effective subsidy rates and implicit subsidies to rich
Commodity Share of consumptionSubsidy /Tax ratesEffective
subsidy
rates(@) Implicit subsidy
to rich (in R
crore) (*)
Rich
Poor Rich Poor
Kerosene 4951-38 -3888 5501
Electricity 8416-32 -4951 37170
LPG 919-36 -3686 40151
Railways 928-34 -6953 3671
Petrol 95561 61_ _
Diesel 98255 55_ _
AT F 100020 2030 762
Gold 9821.6 1.617.4 4093
Sum of Subsidy 91349
Subsidy on account of PPF 11900
Total subsidy to well-off 103249
Source: NSS, Ministry of Railways, PPAC, World Bank, Delhi Electricity Regulatory Commission
Notes:
1 All the figures are in percentage terms, except the last column (which is in R crore).
2 Poor refer to the bottom 30 per cent of the population and rich refer to\
top 70 per cent population, divided based on
expenditure distribution as per NSS data.
3 Negative sign in the column of subsidy/tax rates denotes subsidy rate.
4 Kerosene here refers to the consumption of kerosene under PDS only and not from other sources.
5 There is a blank (_) in the effective subsidy rate for the category Petrol and Diesel as the tax rate on these categories is
already higher than the normative 50 per cent.
@ Effective subsidy rate (for the rich) is the difference between normative tax rate (50 per cent for energy related commodities
and 19 per cent for others) and actual subsidy/tax rate for better-off.
* Implicit subsidy to rich is the effective subsidy rate multiplied by consumption of that commodity by rich.
6.26 We depict this benefit-cost analysis
for a number of commodities, and then
compare it against the actual structure of
taxes/subsidies for a few commodities
(Figure 6.3). The benefit-cost ratio is shown
on the x-axis while the tax/subsidy rate is
shown on the y-axis. In an ideal system of
incentives that gives greater weight to the
welfare of the poor, taxes should be greater
and subsidies lower for richer households:
hence the line should be downward sloping
as shown. Ideally, the higher the benefit-cost
ratio the more is the rationale for a subsidy/
lower tax on that commodity and vice-versa.
Points below the line indicate the measure of
the implicit bounties given to the relatively
better off. And the further away from the line,
the greater the bounty. From the chart, it can be seen, as discussed above, that the largest
bounties (for the better off) are provided for
railways, LPG, gold, and to some extent ATF.
total
suBsIdy approprIated By the
well-off
6.27 The implicit effective subsidy to the
well-off is not just the actual subsidy or tax
(which may be lower than what it should be)
on that commodity, but the difference between
what the tax burden on that commodity
should be on the rich and the actual subsidy/
tax rate. To find the normative tax rate on
the well-off, we assume that average tax on
normal commodities to be the standard rate
recommended by the Subramanian panel on a
Revenue Neutral Rate (RNR) for GST, i.e. 19
Bounties for the Well-Off
104
per cent11, and average tax on energy related
commodities to be 50 per cent (an appropriate
carbon tax). Then the implicit effective
subsidy rate for the well-off is calculated as
the difference between this normative rate (19
per cent or 50 per cent) and the actual subsidy
(measured as a negative number) or the
(positive) tax rate on that commodity/service.
Then based on the consumption by the well-
off, the implicit effective subsidy to rich on
gold, kerosene, LPG, electricity, railways,
and ATF is calculated. The total amounts to
a total of no less than R91,350 crore (Table
3); not to forget that this is an underestimate
of the actual subsidy to the better-off because
of the underestimation of the consumption by
the rich in the NSS. If we add the subsidies
inherent in just the PPF schemes, the total
subsidy to the well-off amounts to above
R1 lakh crore.conclusIon
6.28 There are a fair amount of government
interventions that help the relatively better-
off in society. In many cases, this help takes
the form of explicit subsidization, which
is surprisingly substantial in magnitude.
Addressing these interventions and rectifying
some egregious anomalies may be good not
only from a fiscal and welfare perspective,
but also from a political economy welfare
perspective, lending credibility to other
market-oriented reforms. The R1 lakh crore
of subsidy going to the better-off merely
on account of 6 commodities plus the small
savings schemes represent a substantial
leakage from the government’s kitty, and
an opportunity foregone to help the truly
deserving.
Economic Survey 2015-16
Fiscal Capacity for the 21st Century
07
IntroductIon
7.1 The Indian tax system is about to
witness dramatic changes. Consider first the
GST. Implementing a new tax, encompassing
both goods and services, to be implemented by
the Centre, 28 States and 7 Union Territories,
in a large federal system, via a constitutional
amendment requiring broad political
consensus, affecting potentially 2-2.5 million
excise and service taxpayers, and marshalling
the latest technology to radically improve
collection efficiency, is a reform perhaps
unprecedented in modern global tax history.
7.2 Take next corporate taxes. The rate is
scheduled to come down from 30 percent to 25 percent and a wide range of exemptions
will be phased out in an orderly manner. In
addition, the legacy of contentious, adversarial
tax issues from the past is being cleaned up.
Tax administration is being improved: now
around 95 per cent of filings are electronic, tax
refunds are now being issued in a record 7-8
days, and a new Tax Policy Council and Tax
Research Unit are being created.
7.3
To be sure, a number of important issues
in tax policy as well as in tax administration
(as detailed for example, in the report of the
Tax Administration Reforms Commission)
need to be addressed. But ongoing
developments warrant taking stock of a simple
but fundamental question: Given that state
Fiscal capacity—spending and especially taxation—is key to long run economic
development. Taxation is not just about financing spending, it is the economic
glue that binds citizens to the state in a two-way accountability relationship.
Against this background, we assess India’s fiscal capacity. Simple tax-GDP and
spending-GDP ratios suggest that India under-taxes and under-spends relative
to comparable countries. But, controlling for the level of economic development,
India neither under-taxes nor under-spends. India does tax and spend less than
other politically developed nations, but given that most other democracies took
time to strengthen tax capacity, perhaps India is not an outlier on this dimension,
either. India does stand out in the number of individual income taxpayers,
currently about 4 percent, far from our desirable estimate of about 23 percent.
Building long-run fiscal capacity is vital. One low hanging fruit would be to
refrain from raising exemption thresholds for the personal income tax, allowing
natural growth in income to increase the number of taxpayers. Beyond that,
building fiscal capacity is also about creating legitimacy in the state. This can be
acquired by prioritizing improved delivery of essential services that all citizens
consume.
CHAPTER
106
capacity and taxation are crucial determinants
of long run development, how can India move
from its current situation to one of increasing
taxes and government spending as part of the
process of building state capacity ?
1
7.4 The findings are nuanced but striking.
i. A simple comparison of aggregates with
other countries indicates that India under-
taxes and under-spends.
ii. Controlling for the level of economic
development, India neither under-taxes
nor under-spends.
iii. India does tax and spend less than other
politically developed nations, but given
that most other democracies took a long
time to strengthen tax capacity, perhaps it
is not an outlier on this dimension, either.
iv. Where India does stand out is in the
number of individual income taxpayers.
The ratio of taxpayers to voters is only
about 4 percent, whereas it should be
closer to 23 percent.
7.5 We explore the policy implications of
these findings in the concluding section.
7.6 Consider first, why taxation is key to
long run political and economic development.
If spending is about the entitlements of
citizenship in a democracy, taxation is about
the obligations of citizenship. Taxation and
military service (or some other form of
compulsory national service) are two core
elements of modern citizenship. India has
chosen taxation as the key obligation that it
can demand of its citizens. The obligations
of citizenship are the foundations of nation
building and democracy. Bringing more and
more people into the tax net via some form
of direct taxation, will help in realizing the
promise of Indian democracy.
7.7 Democracy is a contract between the
state and its citizens. This contract has a vital economic dimension: the state's role is to
create the conditions for prosperity for all by
providing essential services and protecting
the less well-off via redistribution. The
citizen's part of the contract is to hold the
state accountable when it fails to honour the
contract (Besley and Persson [2013]
2). But
a citizen's stake in exercising accountability
diminishes if he does not pay in a visible and
direct way for the services the state commits to
providing. If a citizen does not pay - through
taxes or user fees - he either becomes a free
rider (using the service without paying)
or exits (not using the service at all). Both
reduce the accountability of the state. Hence
the expression: no representation without
taxation. Taxation is not just about financing
public spending, it is the economic glue that
binds citizens to the state in a necessary two-
way relationship.
7.8 One can think of tax paying and political
participation as two important accountability
mechanisms wielded by citizens. The
precocious India phenomenon is that economic
development lags political development.
One can hypothesize that this difference
in taxpaying and voting might explain the
phenomenon in India of there being reasonably
effective episodic accountability as opposed to
ongoing accountability. Independent India has
averted famines but chronic malnutrition is
still a challenge. The Indian state can organize
mega-events but routine safety for women has
turned out to be more difficult to achieve. The
Indian state responds effectively to floods and
tsunamis but finds water and power metering
more challenging.
7.9 Consider next the challenge of moving
to a better equilibrium. There are no real low
hanging fruit here because of two reasons:
first, India is not really an outlier, contrary
to much popular perception, in terms of its
1 In this chapter, government spending, henceforth spending, and taxes, are for the general government unless
mentioned otherwise.
2 Besley, T. J. & T. Persson,2013, “Taxation and Development”, CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP9307.
Economic Survey 2015-16
107
overall level of taxation and spending—facts
that we establish unambiguously. It is easy
to exhort the government to, say, increase
spending on health and education or remove
exemptions on the tax side. But it must be
remembered that the ability to spend and tax is
in part endogenous to the perceived legitimacy
of the state. Citizens will be willing to pay
their dues as taxes only if they feel that the
state is adhering to its side of the contract by
delivering essential services. In other words,
tax and spending policy are related to actions
by the state to increase its legitimacy. State and
tax capacity are as much about state legitimacy
as they are about technical details relating the
design of policy and its implementation.
cross-country taxat Ion and
E
xp End Itur E patt Erns
7.10 In this chapter we assess, in a simple
cross-country framework, whether India
taxes and spends enough. How does India,
a democracy with (PPP adjusted) per-capita
GDP at about one-seventh of the OECD
average compare internationally on spending
and taxation patterns? A caveat: we do not
consider property taxation not because it is
unimportant. Rather, the omission owes to
data challenges, stemming in part from the fact
that property is taxed, albeit differently, at all
three levels of government in India. This also
means that the Centre has fewer policy levers
at its disposal so that improving property
taxation will require greater cooperation
between all three levels of government. But
given the extent to which property is a critical
constituent of wealth and a potential source of
local government revenues, property taxation
reforms should be an important part of the
country’s tax reform agenda.
7.11 In the simple cross-section, India
appears to be an outlier: it taxes and spends
less than OECD countries and less than its
emerging market peers (Table 1). India’s
spending to GDP ratio (as well as spending
in human capital i.e. health and education) is lowest among BRICS and lower than both
the OECD and EME averages. India’s tax to
GDP ratio at 16.6 per cent also is well below
the EME and OECD averages of about 21 per
cent and 34 per cent, respectively.
7.12
India’s spending and tax ratios are
the lowest even among economies with
comparable (PPP adjusted) per-capita GDP
e.g. Vietnam, Bolivia and Uzbekistan. The
two ratios stand at 28 per cent and 22.2 per
cent, 43.3 per cent and 25.5 per cent, 33.4 per
cent and 25.6 per cent for Vietnam, Bolivia
and Uzbekistan respectively for the latest
year available. Table 1 also shows that India’s
share of income and property tax in GDP are
also comparatively low (with the exception
of China in case of direct taxation).
7.13 Over time too, it seems, India has made
limited progress in increasing its tax and
spending capacity. Besley and Persson (2013)
document that rich countries have consistently
invested in tax collection capacity and collect
a larger share of income in taxes vis-à-vis
poor nations (and much higher revenues vis-
à-vis poor countries despite comparable tax
rates).In comparison to the United States
(which introduced income taxes over the first
half of the 20th century) India’s tax to GDP
ratio has increased at a much slower pace
over the comparable time period following
the introduction of income taxation. India’s
tax to GDP ratio has increased by about 10
percentage points over the past six decades
from about 6 per cent in 1950-51 to 16.6 per
cent in 2013-14. Figure 1 shows ten-year
snapshots of the trends in aggregate spending
as well as the indirect and direct tax to GDP
ratios for India starting 1960-61.
7.14 However, it may not be appropriate to
make such simple cross-country comparisons
since there is a strong relationship between
a country’s fiscal capacity and the level of
economic development. The correct question
to ask therefore is: whether India’s fiscal
capacity is low given its level of economic
Fiscal Capacity for the 21st Century
108
development (proxied by its PPP adjusted per
capita GDP).
Analysis of Taxation and Expenditure
Patterns: Is India an outlier?
7.15 One way to answer this question is
simply to plot the relationship between
various indicators of fiscal capacity and per
capita GDP and see where India stands. In this
section, we do this for five indicators—overall
3 The database also includes the number of taxpayers and voting age population for each country. Data on voting
age population is from the International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance (IDEA) based on
the most recent elections held in these countries. Number of taxpayers are available for 56 countries and is
taken from the OECD 2011 Report titled “Tax Administration in OECD and Selected Non-OECD Countries:
Comparative Information Series (2010)”. Data on individual income taxes are for 54 countries.
tax to GDP, direct tax to GDP, individual
income tax to GDP, overall expenditure to
GDP, and human capital expenditure to GDP.
7.16 To do this we collect consistent data for
these indicators at the general government
level from multiple sources viz. the OECD
database, World Development Indicators
(World Bank), Government Finance Statistics
(IMF) and Fiscal Monitor (IMF). Our dataset
3
looks at variables including the total tax to
*: Source: Various Economic Surveys and Indian Public Finance Statistics 2014-15.
Table 1: Share as per cent of GDP
Country Total
Ta x Total
Expenditure Expenditure in
human capex* Direct tax
Individual
Income tax Property
taxIndirect
Ta x
China 19.4
29.7 7.25.3 --2.012.7
India 16.6
26.6 5.15.62.10.810.1
Brazil 35.6
40.2 11.07.32.32.015.7
Korea 24.3
20.0 8.47.13.72.57.5
Vietnam 22.2
28.0 8.88.4 ------
South Africa 28.8
32.0 10.715.0 --1.410.2
Turkey 29.3
37.3 7.25.94.11.413.5
Russia 23.0
38.7 7.27.2 --1.1 7.1
UK 32.9
41.4 13.411.7 9.14.010.8
US 25.4
35.7 13.312.0 9.82.94.4
EMEs Avg 21.4
30.9 7.57.42.21.010.8
OECD Avg 34.2
42.8 11.611.5 9.51.911.0
Note: *: Expenditure in health and education, --: Not available. Source: OECD, World Bank, IMF databases and
Ministry of Education, People's Republic of China.
Economic Survey 2015-16
109
4 The regression results reported here are robust to outliers.
GDP, total general government expenditure
as per cent of GDP and expenditures on
education and health in a sample of 77
countries including all OECD countries and
major EMEs for the latest available year. The
results are shown in Figures 2A—2E.
7.17 The results are striking: contrary to
popular perception that India has low fiscal
capacity, each of the charts show that India
does not. It is close to the line of best fit
(shown in red) in all the figures
4. In case of
direct tax and personal income tax, counter to
conventional wisdom, India’s fiscal capacity
seems to be significantly better than the
average.
7.18 The response to this striking finding
could be that it is not enough to control for
Aus
AtrBel
Can
Chi
Cze
Den
Est
FinFra
GerGce
HunIce
IreIsr
Ita
Jap
Kor
Lux
Mex
Net
Nzl
Nor
PolPor
SRP
Slo
Spa
Swe
SwiTur
UK
US
Arg
BulChn
C